CREATING A FUTURES MARKET FOR MAJOR
EVENT TICKETS:PROBLEMS AND PROSPECTS
Stephen K. Happel and Marianne M. Jennings
In a 1995 article in this journal, we discussed the legal, economic,
and ethical concerns in trying to prevent “free-market” ticket scalp-
ing.
1
Since the time that article appeared, the Internet has become a
source of information as well as a business and contract formation
tool. Knowledge, products, and negotiations move in far more effi-
cient manners because of the facilitation of inexpensive communica-
tion and interaction via the Internet. Major event tickets—those that
attract national audiences such as the NFL’s Super Bowl, the PGA’s
Masters, the NCAA Final Four, or even a Bruce Springsteen con-
cert—are traded openly on eBay and other Websites.
Yet, despite the vast amount of personal wealth in the United
States and the relative ease with which consumers can travel to any
event site in the country, the availability of this new technology that
facilitates national and international exchanges of price information
and tickets has not created a nationally organized futures market for
major event tickets. This paper explores this “market failure” and
considers the likelihood of correcting it. The first section examines
the character of tickets, exploring their nature as call options. The
following section looks at the ticket resale statutes of 50 states along
with various municipal statutes and describes the current legal envi-
ronment surrounding ticket sales. The third section considers the
different distribution channels open to potential consumers of major
ticket events. The fourth section reviews recent microeconomic stud-
ies of event pricing and ticket scalping that have appeared since the
time of our previous article. The final section explores the reasons
Cato Journal, Vol. 21, No. 3 (Winter 2002). Copyright © Cato Institute. All rights re-
served.
Stephen K. Happel is Professor of Economics and Marianne M. Jennings is Professor of
Legal and Ethical Studies at Arizona State University.
1
Various magazine and newspaper columnists have concurred. For instance, Seligman
(1999), in listing the 10 dumbest ideas of the 20th century, writes, “We are smart enough
to send men to the moon, yet we still have laws against ticket scalping.”
443
that the major entertainment event ticket market remains fragmented
and examines whether a nationally organized national market will
emerge in the near future.
Major Event Tickets as Call Options
For major events held in stadiums, arenas, amphitheaters, or con-
cert halls with limited seating capacity, tickets are normally put on
sale weeks or months in advance. They are initially sold at a printed
face value (plus, at times, an allowable service charge). The usual
explanation for a printed face value is a preassigned value for pur-
poses of possible refunds despite the reality that refunds from event
organizers are quite rare. In fact, event tickets often indicate on their
faces that (1) they are a revocable license; (2) admission may be
refused; (3) promoters and organizers are not responsible for lost
tickets; and (4) the stated face value may only be repaid under certain
conditions with some tickets actually having NO REFUND printed
on the front. Given the lack of administrative purpose, the real reason
for a printed face value is perhaps the same as the reason for placing
a par value on a common stock or option—the face value is simply a
starting point that provides a legal measure of what is “fair” or “eq-
uitable.”
Tickets to major events share other characteristics with call op-
tions. Because event sponsors do not typically require identification
to enter the event, the tickets become bearer instruments once they
are sold. Like a call option, the holder has the right, but not the
obligation, to occupy (or call in) a certain seat over a certain period of
time.
If tickets as traded today are essentially call options, then it would
follow that such bearer instruments of value could be exchanged, just
like stock options, in a nationally organized futures market. Likewise,
ticket markets could have standard rules of order and trading behav-
ior that are specified for licensed brokers. In such a market, the NFL
could, for example, take the seats designated for the “general public”
for the Super Bowl and have a public offering the day after this year’s
Super Bowl using the tools, access, and customers of the national
exchange. Bid/ask prices could be posted every trading day until the
following Super Bowl. As the game approaches and the two teams are
chosen, those fans entitled to team-based tickets could bring those
tickets into the market and also trade them openly on the national
exchange. A similar approach could be taken for NCAA Final Four
CATO JOURNAL
444
tickets, major concert tours by high-demand artists, or for that matter
the Masters golf tournament.
2
The creation of such a market is, however, dependent on a number
of factors. First, the laws of each state must permit such sales and
resales of tickets. The patchwork quilt of regulations demonstrates
how difficult uniformity of approval for a national futures market
would be. Second, there is the possibility that the market dynamics
and value of major event tickets could change with the ease of access.
While the comparison to call options and the futures market is logical
and major event tickets meet the definition of bearer commodities in
a high-demand market, the actual market for tickets and ticket resales
has unique psychology and composition that can affect traditional
economic solutions with a free market.
U.S. Ticket-Scalping Statutes
There are no federal laws imposing national restrictions or rules on
ticket scalping. In 1998, Congressman Gary Ackerman (D-NY) tried
to introduce the Ticket Scalping Reduction Act, which, if passed,
would have prohibited the sale of five or more tickets in a single
transaction at a markup in excess of $5.00 or 10 percent of the printed
face value (whichever is greater). In a rare example of collective
economic intelligence on both sides of the congressional aisle, no
cosponsors came forward and hearings were never held on the Ack-
erman bill.
Presently, 20 states have no statutes regulating the resale of enter-
tainment tickets, 3 have only minor location restrictions, and 5 have
enabling statutes that confer regulatory authority over the issue to
local governments.
3
Within these so-called “open” states, major mu-
nicipalities including Anaheim, Ann Arbor, Cincinnati, Cleveland,
Dallas, Denver, Las Vegas, Madison, Milwaukee, Richmond, Roa-
noke, Seattle, and Virginia Beach have enacted ordinances restricting
the resale of tickets in some manner.
Strikingly, “the land of the free and the home of the brave” has 22
states that continue to adhere to legal price controls. Those price
controls take on various forms such as mandating allowable markups
on all entertainment tickets (12 states), outlawing scalping for par-
ticular events (8 states), or restricting profitable resale to a limited
2
In May, 2001, the Salt Lake Organizing Committee for the upcoming Olympic Winter
Games took the first positive step in this direction by conducting an Internet ticket auction
for the Winter Game’s most popular events such as figure skating, hockey, and ski jumping.
3
A listing of state statutes on ticket resale is available from the authors upon request.
CREATING A FUTURES MARKET FOR MAJOR EVENT TICKETS
445
segment or segments of the public, such as sales by licensed brokers
(2 states). New York State, the very epicenter of financial markets,
presently has one of the strictest anti-scalping regulatory schemes in
the country (New York has regulated resale prices of tickets since
1822). In 2001, New York made it illegal for any person, firm, or
corporation to resell a ticket for more than $5.00 or 20 percent above
face value, whichever is greater (from 1984 to 2001 the markup was
$5.00 or 10 percent, and prior to that, $2.00 a ticket). Resale of tickets
is prohibited within 1,000 feet of a place of entertainment having a
permanent seating capacity of 5,000 persons and ticket brokers must
be licensed. Lastly, the practice of “ice” (insider trading where box
office employees channel tickets to brokers and scalpers for a fee) was
changed from a misdemeanor to a felony in 2001.
These statutes will be revisited in June 2003, due to sunset provi-
sions. The attorney general of New York, Eliot L. Spitzer, indicated
in the New York Times that if the problem of brokers illegally ob-
taining large blocks of tickets could be eliminated, his office would
consider supporting the removal of price restrictions on ticket resales
and going to a free market (Tierney 2000: B1) Laissez-faire advocates
can only hope that New Yorkers finally see the light after 80 years of
price restrictions.
Our previous work differentiated “first-generation” scalping laws,
those representing the early wave of ticket regulation that attempted
to curb the relatively confined activities of on-site scalpers, from
“second-generation” laws, those that were part of the next wave of the
regulatory trends that recognized the segmented markets in second-
ary ticket sales. The second generation of anti-scalping statutes care-
fully segmented street scalpers from ticket agents/brokers. Many of
these “second-generation” laws remain in effect because of the sup-
port from the public on the emotional aspects of controlling what is
perceived to be pushy and price-gouging scalpers.
Throughout the past decade, the law review literature (e.g., Rabe
1991, Zankel 1992, Criscuolo 1995, Kandel and Block 1997, Gibbs
2000) has uniformly called for more extensive ticket market legisla-
tion to protect the public from extortion and control of the market by
sellers. Some of the specific problems cited with street scalping in-
clude: creation or aggravation of traffic congestion, drug dealing,
fraudulent sales of bogus tickets, and misrepresentation of seat loca-
tions. The articles also approach the issue from the egalitarian argu-
ment of ensuring public access to entertainment and sports events as
well as the generic arguments on public welfare. Uniformly, those
writing in the field support the rights of promoters, owners, and
artists to decide on both pricing and distribution mechanisms.
CATO JOURNAL
446
There is little variation in the analysis from the perspective of legal
scholars: consumers of major event tickets are “innocents,” and bro-
kers and scalpers are “evil manipulators.” This perspective had been
carried through to the regulations, statutes, and ordinances of both
generations of laws. No state or local statutes impose fines or jail
sentences on the buyers of tickets, only on the sellers. Illinois even
provides a civil remedy for a ticket purchaser who purchases a ticket
at an “overcharge” price: “Whoever feels himself aggrieved or injured
by paying for such tickets in excess of the advertised price or printed
rate has a right to recover for each ticket for which an overcharge was
made contrary to the provisions for the act, a sum of $100.00.”
While the second generation laws and ordinances continued their
popularity in adoption and enforcement, there was one notable ex-
ception to heavy-handed regulatory controls of on-site ticket scalping
on event days. In 1995, the Phoenix City Council held open hearings
on the issue of on-site scalping to explore alternatives to regulation.
Following the hearings, the council passed an ordinance that herded
all street scalpers into one location in the city, an empty lot across
from the main entrance to the Phoenix Suns arena. Used first for the
NBA All-Star Game that year, under the terms of this ordinance,
anyone could sell tickets at any price within the designated location
with no license required.
The ordinance remains in effect because it addresses problems that
are the focus of the legal literature. Since those selling tickets are in
one location, street congestion caused by consumers searching for
tickets sellers is avoided, fans are not hassled on the way to the game,
and the area is easy to police. The Phoenix experiment also has shown
that long-standing street scalpers do not knowingly trade in counter-
feit or stolen tickets and report any such activity to the police. The
Phoenix free-market alternative not only created a competitive pric-
ing atmosphere, it overcame nuisance effects. It functioned well dur-
ing the 2001 World Series, with ticket buyers witnessing declining
prices as game times neared.
Consumers Acquiring Tickets and the Extent of the
Primary and Secondary Markets
For those who wish to attend a major entertainment event, a series
of options exist for acquiring tickets. One is to simply go to the official
(team) box office, stand in line, and then pay the printed face value
(plus taxes) for tickets. A slight modification of this option is available
CREATING A FUTURES MARKET FOR MAJOR EVENT TICKETS
447
when the “box office” allows phone-in or e-mail orders that are sub-
sequently picked up at the will-call window.
4
For some events (e.g., the Super Bowl or the NCAA Final Four) no
“box office” exists prior to the event. Instead, the general public plays
the odds by submitting names for the possible award of tickets. A
small number of names are randomly chosen and the winners are
permitted to buy tickets for such events at face value. A random
system is also used when local radio stations stage promotional give-
aways that offer consumers the opportunity to win tickets through a
game or drawing.
Another option for consumers is to purchase tickets from an offi-
cially designated ticket agent. The largest such ticket agent in the
United States is Ticketmaster, with Tickets.com a distant rival. Agents
sell tickets through retail outlets, by telephone, or through secure
online sites, adding a service fee (roughly $4.50 per ticket for an
inventory that carries an average ticket face value of $33.00) for their
role in matching consumers to events. According to the Kelsey Group
(1999), Ticketmaster represents 94 of the 118 professional teams in
baseball, basketball, football, and hockey, and has 4,300 exclusive
worldwide relationships with local event venues and promoters, while
Tickets.com claims 4,000 such relationships. Ticketmaster’s ticket
revenues in 1998 were $316 million ($70 million of which were online
sales), with Tickets.com’s revenues in 1998 being $29.8 million ($5.3
online sales). Ticketmaster Group accounted for 16 percent of all
tickets sold in 1998.
The forgoing options constitute the primary ticket market for sport-
ing and entertainment events. Using data from U.S. Statistical Ab-
stracts, Variety, Newsday, Amusement Business, Team Marketing Re-
port, and the League of American Theaters and Productions,
TicketAmerica (1998) derived an estimate of $7.2 billion spent
through primary ticket channels in 1997. The Kelsey Group (1999)
gives estimates and forecasts of total ticket sales from 1999 to 2004 as
$14.5 billion, $16.25 billion, $18.1 billion, $19.9 billion, $21.9 billion,
and $24.4 billion, respectively. LiquidSeats (2001) estimates the face
value of all tickets sold in the United States for live events and at-
tractions in 1999 to be $16.7 billion. In contrast, TickAuction.com
(2000) finds the primary ticket market to be over $41 billion in 2002,
and EventTixx finds the “Tier 1 Event Marketplace” (major league
4
The A-List music acts (e.g., Madonna, ‘NSync, the Backstreet Boys, and Aerosmith) are
increasingly selling concert tickets on the Web in advance—conducting presales—largely to
members of online fan clubs or subscribers to Internet-access services like MSN and
America Online (Peers and Mathews 2001).
CATO JOURNAL
448
sports, college football and basketball, concerts, Broadway theater,
select golf and tennis tournaments, etc.) to have ticket sales in excess
of $60 billion in 2000. The disparity among the estimates is best
explained by the fact that they encompass different segments of the
entertainment industry. However, all the estimates establish that the
size of the primary ticket market is massive.
Because entertainment event tickets are sold in advance, a second-
ary (resale) market naturally develops. Sellers in this market include
relatives, friends, business acquaintances, travel agents, tour group
operators, concierges, auctioneers on the Internet, brokers, and scalp-
ers.
Estimates for the number of recognized U.S. ticket brokers range
from 800 (EventTixx 2000) to over 1,000 (LiquidSeats 2001). These
brokers typically serve only a single metropolitan area or geographic
area. The broker industry is highly fragmented, comprised primarily
of small businesses that, on average, have 10 to 15 employees and
annual sales revenues of $3 to 4 million. No single broker controls
more than 1 percent of the secondary market (EventTixx 2000). Tick-
ets are acquired through every legal means possible (standing in line,
hiring others to stand in line, staging mass telephone calls and e-mails
for soliciting tickets, making special arrangements with season ticket
holders or players and artists, infiltrating fan clubs, and trading with
other brokers). Some 25 to 40 percent of all broker ticket sales involve
“try and get” tickets, advance sales not in current inventory that must
be secured (often from other brokers). Approximately 50 percent of
all brokers have a Web site and 95 percent of them default to a model
that has them advertising tickets on a “by-area” basis for specific
events.
TicketAmerica (1998), using its primary market estimate of $7.2
billion for 1997, assumes that brokers resell 10 percent of the primary
market and double their prices, which leads to an estimate of $1.4
billion for the secondary broker market. Similarly, EventTixx (2000)
believes that brokers currently have a $2 to 3 billion slice of the $60
billion “Tier 1 Event Marketplace.” However, LiquidSeats (2001),
using a larger estimate of the primary market and assuming that
brokers resell some 20 to 30 percent of the top-tiered seats and then
employ a 50 percent mark-up, estimates the secondary market to be
in the $10–14 billion range in 2000.
Because the ticket broker market is not an integrated one,
TicketAmerica attempted to fill the void in 1998 by undertaking ef-
forts to organize brokers into a national exchange. Founded by indi-
viduals with extensive experience in both business-to-business and
retail electronic transaction processing and the ticket brokerage in-
CREATING A FUTURES MARKET FOR MAJOR EVENT TICKETS
449
dustry itself, TicketAmerica worked with trade groups like the East
Coast Ticket Brokers Association and the National Association of
Ticket Brokers to link brokers around the country in the “first verti-
cally integrated portal for reselling premium tickets for high demand
sports and entertainment events.” TicketAmerica’s goal was to be the
primary Internet retailer, making an inventory of the best seats avail-
able to the general public at the click of a mouse. In addition,
TicketAmerica hoped to be the first Application Service Provider for
the ticket broker community, offering the independent ticket brokers
a fully integrated e-business solution site. Yet even though “few bro-
kers have the infrastructure necessary to efficiently run their own
business and none have the ability to make the infrastructure invest-
ment required to “organize” the market,” TicketAmerica did not suc-
ceed.
5
The same is true for TickAuction.com, another venture to
create a broker-to-broker network in the late 1990s. Trying to organize
the fiercely independent group of ticket brokers is like herding cats.
The secondary market also has offered the Internet as a direct
option for consumers. The overwhelming consensus among those
analyzing and consulting for the event ticket market is that online
sales will continue to skyrocket. EventTixx (2000) reports that the
number of Ticketmaster tickets sold on the Web relative to traditional
retail and telesales channels had grown from less than .1 percent in
1996 to 24.8 percent by the 2nd quarter of 2000; and Ticketmaster
now faces increasing competition from niche players, such as Cul-
ture.Finder.com, that sell tickets online for smaller events. The Kel-
sey Group (1999) projects that the share of total U.S. ticket sales
revenues that occur online will increase from 2 percent in 1999 to
17.5 percent in 2004. LiquidSeats (2001) anticipates that online sales
of event tickets will grow at a 58 percent compound annual growth
through 2006.
While 50 percent of ticket brokers in the secondary market have
Web sites offering seats, few are doing significant ticket sales via
e-commerce. In aggregate, LiquidSeats (2001) estimates that the In-
ternet accounted for less than 4 percent of secondary market sales in
2000. Buyers in the secondary market are not going to brokers online.
Instead, they are heading to auction sites.
Local newspaper, radio, and television station Web sites provide
ticket buyers and sellers direct access to trade through an auction
format. Tickets.com and OpenSeats.com, attempting to be full service
providers, provide auction service as well. eBay has recently expanded
its offerings to include major event tickets. While event ticket busi-
5
Quotes are from TicketAmerica’s prospectus.
CATO JOURNAL
450
ness remains a small percentage of total auction sales, its sports-
tickets auctions grew 200 percent from July 2000 to March 2001
(Walker 2001). Accordingly, the company is anticipating very strong
growth over the coming decade.
The secondary Internet market underwent radical change starting
in 1999. Firms with highly refined software packages approached
major sports teams and event promoters with an offer to resell (sea-
son) tickets at designated Web sites. In exchange, the owners or
promoters would receive a set fee. While SeasonTickets.com and
LiquidSeats were in business before June 2000, what captured na-
tional attention was the San Francisco Giants Double Play Ticket
Window rolled out that month (Sports Illustrated 2000).
The way it works is that a season ticket holder logs onto the official
Giants Web site and sets a fixed price for excess seats (here the price
had to be above face value because the Giants did not want to alienate
other season ticket holders by underselling tickets). After fans buy the
tickets, they are picked up at the will-call window at the stadium,
thereby avoiding delivery and counterfeit problems. The Giants,
through their licensed agent, receive a fee of 10 percent from both
the seller and the buyer, getting revenues that would otherwise go to
brokers and scalpers.
SeasonTickets.com, currently the biggest player in this type of trad-
ing, and LiquidSeats operate in a similar fashion with their clients, the
only difference being that their Web site prices are not necessarily set
above face value. TicketMaster entered this market in January 2002
and expects significant revenues through strategic partnerships.
Going a step further is Global eTicket Exchange. GEE proposes to
conduct IPO-like auctions for tickets in the primary market rather
than selling tickets at face value. All tickets are electronic, whereby
the buyer uses a special device (e.g., a smart card) to enter the event,
so tickets are no longer general bearer instruments that can be readily
traded after the initial purchase. Instead, if the buyer wants to resell
the ticket, it must be done through GEE’s secondary market Web
site, thus pushing aside brokers and scalpers. GEE also proposes to
increase concession and team-shop sales by providing detailed spend-
ing profiles of its ticket buyers and formulating integrated pricing
strategies and promotions. At the time this article was written, GEE
had not raised the requisite capital for startup, but it had submitted
six business pricing processes to the U.S. Patent Office.
Finally, for those buyers who do not have the need to purchase
tickets days, weeks, or months in advance, or who decide at the last
minute to attend, there is the original secondary market of street
scalpers who operate near the stadium or concert hall on event day.
CREATING A FUTURES MARKET FOR MAJOR EVENT TICKETS
451
Without this secondary market timed to coincide with the event,
consumer options will remain restricted. The market for these types
of events does not deepen until just before the event, and on-site
trading facilitates clearing of the market at its peak.
Pricing Issues
A distinguishing characteristic of the major entertainment industry
until recently has been a lack of extensive price discrimination. While
symphony and opera houses often have 25 or more different ticket
prices depending upon seat location and quality of the event, major
rock concerts may have only two or three ticket prices. Indeed, when
the Rolling Stones tour the United States, the same printed face value
is charged in all venues for all seats. Similarly, major sports leagues
have rules that for a given seat, the same price (printed face value) is
normally charged for each game over the season regardless of the
quality of the opponent. Four microeconomic explanations are pos-
sible for the lack of price discrimination at major events.
The first explanation is that symphony and opera producers under-
stand the preferences and economic characteristics of their fan bases
far more completely than major league sports teams or national per-
formance artists whose fan base consists of thousands of potential fans
who span all socioeconomic groups. Symphony and opera producers
are able to capitalize on well-recognized differing elasticities of de-
mand for alternative seat locations in their venues.
A second explanation for the lack of price discrimination is the
possibility that for events like the Super Bowl or Bruce Springsteen
concerts, most potential attendees place a much greater value on
getting into the event than on occupying a particular seat. Tickets for
these concerts are perceived to be relatively homogeneous goods by
much of the concert-buying public. In opera, seeing the emotion on
the face of a singer may be important and a seat that permits that
close examination is worth more. At football games and rock concerts,
large screens visible from all seats in the arena permit such close
examination. Further, the magnitude of the sound experience may
make a seat’s location irrelevant. The same cannot be said about the
experience of hearing a tenor or soprano. Sensory differences, differ-
ences among customer bases, and the nature of these events preclude
extensive price discrimination.
A third explanation is that complementary concession sales at the
event are much more lucrative for major sporting events and concerts
than for symphonies and operas. General admission seats are priced
uniformly low as a loss leader in order to attract a sell-out crowd that
CATO JOURNAL
452
will produce concession revenue that the promoter is able to predict
with accuracy in advance of pricing tickets for the concerts. The large
sums expended by attendees at the concession stands are character-
istic of sporting and concert events, but not operas.
A final explanation is that certain artists such as U-2, Pearl Jam, and
Garth Brooks assuage their fan bases with the notion of charging a
“fair” price for their concert tickets. Billy Joel and Bruce Springsteen
have stated that they keep their ticket prices low because their “true
fans” are important to them. Such pricing stances are an attraction to
an event in and of itself; indeed, dedication to low ticket prices com-
pletes the aura of “blue collar” some of these artists have cultivated.
If such artists scale the house, they risk creating a public perception
as price gougers, thereby hurting their reputations and long-run box
office sales.
Regardless of the specific explanations for not scaling the house in
the past, the primary market appears poised to make a sharp change.
The slowing economy, increased competition for the public’s enter-
tainment dollar, and better information will allow promoters to en-
gage in a more cautious but thorough form of price discrimination.
In recent microeconomic literature on pricing, Steven Landsburg’s
1993 insightful piece, “Why Popcorn Costs More at the Movies and
Why the Obvious Answer Is Wrong”, has important implications for
sports owners, artists, and promoters. Landsburg’s fundamental
theme is that owners and promoters are selling a package that en-
compasses the ticket to enter and the complementary purchases that
take place at the movie.
Suppose consumers, broadly speaking, have some total amount in
mind that they are willing to pay for the package deal of ticket and
complementary items. Profit-maximizing sellers are going to think
first about attracting those consumers who are willing to pay the most
for the overall package. Promoters and producers are going to try to
discover the prices different customers will pay.
When a consumer chooses to watch a movie and buy a box of
popcorn, assume that he or she is indifferent to paying $7 for the
admission ticket and $1 for the popcorn or $5 for the ticket and $3 for
the popcorn. While the consumer may be indifferent, the seller or
theater owner is not. The cheap popcorn attracts popcorn lovers and
makes them pay a higher price at the door. But to take advantage of
this, movie prices may become so high they drive away nonsnackers
who come only to see the movie.
In contrast, expensive ($3) popcorn allows sellers to extract differ-
ent total sums from different customers. Popcorn lovers, by having
more fun at the movies, are ultimately charged more in total than
CREATING A FUTURES MARKET FOR MAJOR EVENT TICKETS
453
nonsnackers. Indeed, as Landsburg notes, “expensive popcorn makes
sense only if popcorn lovers are really willing to pay more than other
people for their evenings at the theater.”
Extending the argument to major entertainment events, those con-
sumers sitting in particularly good seats may appear to be buying the
seats at a price below market value, but they spend so much on
concessions that total profits are maximized. Relative ticket prices do
not decline markedly for the lower quality seats because the pure
watchers (nonsnackers) are attracted to the event. For the very worst
seats, those that would often go unused at “standard” prices, sellers
may practically give them away as part of a marketing tool because
some of the consumers of lower quality seats will purchase the rela-
tively expensive snacks. Owners and promoters who have achieved a
delicate balance between ticket prices and concession prices across
groups with different elasticities are loathe to make any changes that
upset their complex pricing equilibrium.
In 1994, DeSerpa took the property rights of ticket holders explic-
itly into account in examining the pricing decisions by sellers, the
nature and extent of product differentiation, and the relative impor-
tance of audience participation in major events. For professional
sports leagues, he found that team anticipation of a high number of
sellouts, combined with unexplained variance in the markets of spe-
cific games, gives rise to a relatively simple solution to promote season
ticket sales and a strong secondary market. Assuming a perfect resale
market, the rational seller can apply the same pricing structure to all
games: relatively low-demand games will be overpriced and relatively
high-demand ones will be underpriced.
However, in the absence of a strong resale market (due to anti-
scalping legislation), teams may attempt to anticipate price fluctua-
tions and charge different prices for each game. Even if such a pricing
approach were feasible and inexpensive, adverse fan reaction would
likely make the gains small compared to uniform pricing. If sellers
instead try to maximize expected revenue relative to a uniform price
constraint, season tickets must be discounted because those unable to
attend would, at best, recoup what they paid and, at worst, be left with
an unused ticket for the events they cannot attend.
For the playoffs, sellers do not “exploit” their season ticket holders
by charging very high market-clearing prices because, if they did, they
would sell far fewer season tickets thereafter. Season-ticket priority
rights would become worthless. As DeSerpa (1994: 513) notes, “If the
seller does not charge the static monopoly price and buyers ‘knew’ (or
expected) that he would not, the playoff ‘windfall’ is already internal-
ized into the price of the season ticket.”
CATO JOURNAL
454
Turning to concert tickets, DeSerpa (1994: 515) points out that
one-time concerts are the archetype “mob good” wherein audience
reactions and participation are consumed jointly with the perfor-
mance itself. He argues that the appropriate theoretical analogy is the
set of externalities created by a club in which individual members
consume the characteristics of other members. Sellers can put a price
tag on one part of the transaction, but not on the other. Thus, highest-
demand buyers in terms of money price are not typically the “best
audience,” and the result of excess demand is a change in the ex-
pected audience reaction (the noise level) by expanding the “popu-
lation” from which the actual audience is drawn. By allowing rela-
tively low-demand, raucous buyers a chance of admission, demand
prices increase for all potential buyers, with the maximum price re-
flecting a balance of “the various continuums of economic forces”
(DeSerpa 1994: 517).
The econometric work by Williams (1994) on the economic impact
of anti–ticket scalping laws on ticket prices across the National Foot-
ball League (NFL) is also instructive in understanding event pricing.
Individual teams price their tickets according to competition (what
other entertainment events in the area and other NFL teams are
charging combined with what is perceived to be the entertainment
value of the players being fielded).
The dependent variable in the NFL ticket-pricing equation is the
average 1992 season ticket price for each NFL team. Concession-
pricing issues are ignored. The independent variables in the regres-
sion equation include team-specific variables (average player salary,
team quality as measured by recent conference standings and Super
Bowl performances, stadium capacity) and economic variables (popu-
lation of a team’s market, per capita income in the market, whether
two NFL teams play in the same market). Dummy variables are used
to divide the sample into cities with relatively vigorous anti-scalping
laws and those with relatively weak or nonexistent laws.
Anti-scalping laws are found to affect pricing. When fans can freely
and easily resell their tickets, NFL teams charge higher prices.
Williams’ explanation for this finding is that legal scalping pro-
vides the team whose tickets are resold an active secondary market
with better information about market-clearing prices. Indeed, the
secondary market in those team locations provides a dollar measure
for the magnitude of underpricing. Looking strictly at cross-sectional
season ticket prices, Williams concludes that if NFL owners followed
their economic self-interests, they would vigorously oppose any laws
that prevented or interfered with the scalping of tickets above face
value.
CREATING A FUTURES MARKET FOR MAJOR EVENT TICKETS
455
Marburger (1997), like Landsburg, starts with concessions as
complementary products to the actual product of performance goods
like movies or sporting events. Because the number of available seats
is fixed, the variable costs associated with the number of tickets are
assumed to be virtually nil. These factors suggest a standard model of
rent in which the profit-maximizing price is the revenue-maximizing
price at unitary elasticity. However, because a ticket buyer gains
access to both the performance and the concessions, tickets are
priced below unitary elasticity in the inelastic region to increase the
number of concession patrons. This conclusion provides a theoretical
foundation for empirical studies in the 1970s, 80s, and 90s cited by
Marburger that produce point elasticity estimates in the inelastic
range.
Rosen and Rosenfield (1997) use the theory of classes-of-service
price discrimination to analyze some commonly observed practices of
ticket sellers under conditions of deterministic demand. Their work
illustrates how catering to any subset of customer tastes in one class
constrains the revenues that can be extracted from groups in other
classes. While discriminatory price differentials separate buyers into
somewhat homogeneous groups, substitution opportunities in other
classes invariably limit the surplus that can be extracted from them.
The model employed assumes sellers offer two kinds of seats, high-
quality and low-quality, and then subsequently choose the number of
seats, the quality of each class, a pricing policy for complementary
goods sold on the promises to ticket holders, along with the prices of
tickets themselves. All customers prefer the high-quality seats, but
their willingness to pay varies. Sellers know the frequency of demand
prices distributed over the population but cannot identify the specific
tastes of individual buyers. They also know how the reservation-price
distribution changes as seat quality and the prices of complementary
goods vary. Finally, sellers are assumed to be extremely selfish and do
not wish to allow others to gain financially from the resale of tickets,
thereby precluding secondary markets.
The pricing problem in this model is solved in two steps. First,
given the quantities and qualities of the two seat classes and the price
of complements, sellers choose ticket prices to maximize revenue.
Second, given the optimal pricing policy, sellers decide on the quan-
tity and quality of seats and on the price of complements. The con-
clusion is that the joint distribution of reservation prices for different
quality categories is an important determinant of an optimal price
schedule.
For example, discrimination is greater in high-quality than low-
quality categories when the marginal variance of demand prices is
CATO JOURNAL
456
greater for the high-quality category. Similarly, theater-size con-
straints require repeated production, a kind of “batch processing” of
audiences of given size until all demand is served. Class of service
broadly corresponds to rank in the intertemporal queue: attending
earlier performances is high quality and later performances is low
quality. Prices decline over time to sort customers by tastes, with
sellers finding more ardent customers buying earlier if prices are
declining slowly enough to keep them from waiting but quickly
enough to kept ardent buyers from purchasing too early. In a sense,
customers with the most intense preferences for the service are the
most “exploited,” as measured by price-cost margins. Ticket prices are
lowered and complement prices are set above marginal costs when
the average customer buys more complements than the marginal
customer.
Leslie (1999), relying upon the Broadway play Seven Guitars, for-
mulates a model that includes both second- and third-degree price
discrimination to analyze the welfare implications of such behavior.
The marginal cost of every ticket sold for a given performance is
assumed to be effectively zero, and capacity constraints are not a
binding issue. The goal of the firm is simply then to maximize rev-
enues from ticket sales. Moreover, because there are no subscrip-
tions, concerns about ticket bundling for series of different shows are
precluded.
Distinctions are made between full-price sales (those for a specific
area of seating ranging from orchestra to standing room) and discount
sales (those available only to individuals receiving coupons in the mail
or at given restaurant locations) that result in relatively high-quality
seats being purchased. Consumers must physically present them-
selves on the day of the performance at the discount booth to obtain
a discount ticket, and the number of such tickets made available at the
booth varies day by day and is inversely related to the demand for
tickets in the other categories.
Among Leslie’s findings, the observed price discriminations may
improve the firm’s profit by approximately 5 percent compared to
uniform pricing, while the difference for aggregate consumer welfare
is negligible. Also, the gain from price discrimination depends sig-
nificantly on the magnitude of the discount offered at the booth on
the day of the performance. And in the face of capacity constraints for
each of the different seat-quality regions within the theater, high
demand for some performances implies rationing that leads certain
consumers to purchase their second (or worst) preferred ticket option.
Swofford (1999) begins by citing McCloskey (1985) as the typical
textbook analysis of ticket scalping, whereby scalpers reallocate tick-
CREATING A FUTURES MARKET FOR MAJOR EVENT TICKETS
457
ets that owners and promoters planned to sell on a first-come-first-
served basis at set prices to those who are most willing to pay for
them. Even if ticket scalpers are able to perfectly price discriminate,
no one pays more for a ticket than their reservation price. Allocative
efficiency is thus enhanced, but consumer surplus is reduced and, in
the limit, eliminated.
Swofford then turns to the issue of why a profit-maximizing firm
would allow the purchase of its product (tickets) for speculation and
arbitrage. At least three explanations are possible. One is that uncer-
tainty and risk on the part of primary sellers provides opportunity for
speculation and less risk-adverse brokers. For example, the producer
of a new play sells many seats to early performances to brokers and
scalpers (serving as underwriters) to cover costs in case the show
opens to less-than-stellar reviews.
A second reason is that primary sellers’ producing costs may be
driven up substantially if they try to prevent the secondary market.
The ticket scalper is more an arbitrager than a speculator in this case.
The scalper is able to arbitrage because of lower information costs,
lower transaction costs, or lower taxes. Local scalpers may simply
know more about the local market for a concert than performers or
their agents.
A third reason is that revenue functions are different. The ticket
scalper may be a superior price discriminator when compared to the
primary seller. In addition, the primary seller may be more identified
with the product than the scalper. The scalper examines static profits
while the primary seller looks at dynamic profits. The present value of
long-run profits from repeat business in different shows may be
greater than the static gain from higher revenues on a particular show.
Courty (2000) provides an extensive overview of ticket pricing in
the entertainment industry over the past several decades. He con-
cludes that existing microeconomic theory has been successful in
explaining price variations observed in ticket markets. At the same
time, prices do not vary as much as researchers would predict under
either a competitive or monopoly assumption.
A Nationally Organized Futures Market?
Extensive wealth and relative ease of travel in the United States
have created a national market for major sporting and entertainment
events. Given the advances in information technology and the nature
of tickets, some format analogous to the Chicago Board of Options
seems logical for the secondary ticket market. Yet no such market has
evolved. The question is why.
CATO JOURNAL
458
Technical reasons may provide a partial explanation. For extensive
futures trading, products must be homogeneous, but tickets to most
major events may not be perceived as such. Another explanation is
that the market is not “deep” enough because very few tickets will
actually be traded on a day-to-day basis. More decisive is the wide-
spread opposition by many sellers of tickets. While extensive second-
ary markets help owners and promoters by providing greater infor-
mation on seat prices, concession sales are stripped away from the
entertainment package. The delicate pricing balance that owners and
promoters seek to achieve between ticket price and anticipated
complementary sales is upset. In addition, owners and promoters may
be loathe to allow others to make any profits in which they have no share.
Many small ticket brokers and street scalpers are opposed to a
nationally organized market as well. Such a market would mean that
local customers are no longer highly dependent on them to secure
good seats for special events. In fact, the general trend does not look
promising for small, highly localized sellers, except perhaps on event
day, even if a nationally organized market does not arise. Online
trading, where secondary sellers and buyers can interact directly, is a
powerful and growing force that reduces the need for the small bro-
ker to serve as a middleman in the advance market.
Finally, there is the general public’s opposition to highly organized,
day-to-day futures trading. Current distribution schemes of the NFL
for the Super Bowl, the NCAA for the Final Four, and the Masters
Golf Tournament do allow an average person to get into those events
occasionally without having great wealth or knowing the right people.
Such attendance may become a watershed moment in a person’s life.
A nationally organized market, rightly or wrongly, is perceived to
create a ticket market in which those who can afford to pay end up
with all the seats. Cries of price gouging become the passionate con-
cern for those who want fair prices and access.
A secondary market may disturb the psychological factors in major
event attendance. A secondary market changes the delicate pricing
mechanism arrived at by event promoters and team owners. The
partnership format appears to satisfy the primary market sellers while
not alienating the potential customers in the secondary market with
perceptions of price gouging. As this market format takes hold, ever
more complicated pricing models lie in wait for the microeconomic
literature as complementary and intertemporal factors are weighed
both directly and in relation to hedging opportunities by various busi-
ness concerns.
Given present technological and market constraints, there are sev-
eral paths the development of a secondary market could take. One
CREATING A FUTURES MARKET FOR MAJOR EVENT TICKETS
459
path is that a technologically savvy company captures much of the
secondary market and offers a national mechanism whereby sellers
and buyers can use a service for ticket sales and purchases. However,
such an approach would require that any company providing the
market would hold a substantial number of tickets for a variety of
events, including sports, concerts, and other one-time events.
Another possibility is that ticket sellers could create a nonbearer
ticket instrument, akin to airline e-tickets, a type of instrument that
could be traded only through the promoter’s organization or Web
site. Such an approach would permit the owners and promoters to
capture the secondary market because of the inability of secondary
market participants to overcome the nonbearer quality of the tickets.
Owners and promoters would enjoy the benefits of the secondary
market sales and the distinction between the primary and secondary
markets could disappear.
The creation of an ideal futures market for tickets would be one
operated in a technologically advanced fashion that provides full ac-
cess to tickets and prices as well as open access for all buyers and
sellers, including event promoters and team owners. Such an open
market would require bearer types of instruments because the use of
e-tickets by the promoters and owners would create the secondary
market usurpation noted earlier. Additionally, the on-site trading re-
mains a critical part of the ideal futures market because the nature of
these events and buyer psychology is such that the market does not
fully deepen until the event is imminent. The ultimate decision to
attend an event occurs at varying times during the event and ticket
cycle, but the full market effect is not captured unless those final
hours and moments of trading are also captured.
One of the possible results of such a market is the potential for
hedging among promoters and owners, particularly with sports. Own-
ers could hedge some of the risk associated with season failures that
could come from terrorist types of attacks, weather, and other force
majeure events that could delay, interrupt, or shorten the season in
one sport.
It is impossible to predict the reaction of the public to such selling
approaches. The psychological factor remains a wild card in the evo-
lution of the secondary market, and its success is dependent upon
consumer comfort with and acceptance of such a market.
References
Courty, P. (2000) “An Economic Guide to Ticket Pricing in the Entertain-
ment Industry.” Louvain Economic Review 66:167–89.
CATO JOURNAL
460
Criscuolo, P. (1995) “Comment: Reassessing the Ticket Scalping Dispute:
The Application, Effects, and Criticisms of Current Anti-Scalping Legis-
lation.” Seton Hall Journal of Sports Law 5: 189–99.
DeSerpa, A. (1994) “To Err Is Rational: A Theory of Excess Demand for
Tickets.” Managerial and Decision Economics 15: 511–18.
EventTixx (2000) “Executive Summary.” Austin, Tex.
Gibbs, J. (2000) “Cyberscalping: On-Line Ticket Sales.” Toledo Law Review
31: 471–95.
Happel, S., and Jennings, M. (1989) “Assessing the Economic Rationale and
Legal Remedies for Ticket Scalping.” Journal of Legislation 16:1–14.
Happel, S., and Jennings, M. (1995) “The Folly of Anti-Scalping Laws.” Cato
Journal 15: 65–80.
Kandel, A., and Block, E. (1997) “The ‘De-Icing’ of Ticket Prices: A Proposal
Addressing the Problem of Commercial Bribery in the New York Ticket
Industry.” Journal of Law and Policy 5: 489–508.
Kelsey Group (1999) “Online Ticketing Outlook.” Princeton, N.J.
Landsburg, S. (1993) “Why Popcorn Costs More at the Movies and Why the
Obvious Answer Is Wrong.” In The Armchair Economist: Economics and
Everyday Life. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Leslie, P. J. (1999) “Price Discrimination in Broadway Theatre.” Mimeo,
U.C.L.A. Department of Economics.
LiquidSeats (2001) “Executive Summary.” San Francisco, Calif.
Marburger, D. R. (1997) “Optimal Ticket Pricing for Performance Goods.”
Managerial and Decision Economics 18: 375–82.
McCloskey, D. (1985) The Applied Theory of Price. 2nd ed. New York:
Macmillian.
Peers, M., and Mathews, A. W. (2001) “Plugged-In Fans Buy Hot Tickets in
Web ‘Presales’.” Wall Street Journal, 21 May: B1, B5.
Rabe, S. (1991) “Ticket Scalping: Free Market Mirage.” American Journal of
Criminal Law 19: 57–69.
Rosen, S., and Rosenfield, A. (1997) “Ticket Pricing.” Journal of Law and
Economics 40: 351–75.
Seligman, D. (1999) “Dumbest Ideas of the Century.” Forbes, 27 December:
94, 96.
Swofford, J. (1999) “Arbitrage, Speculation, and Public Policy toward Ticket
Scalping.” Public Finance Review 27: 531–40.
Sports Illustrated (2000) “E-Scalping?” 28 August: 64.
TickAuction.com (2000) “Executive Summary.” Marietta, Ga.
TicketAmerica (1998) “Executive Summary.” Minneapolis, Minn.
Tierney, J. (2000) “Infringing on the Right to Be Scalped.” New York Times,
24 October: B1.
Walker, S. (2001) “Seats in the Cheap.” Wall Street Journal, 9 March: W1,
W10.
Williams, A. T. (1994) “Do Anti-Scalping Laws Make a Difference?” Mana-
gerial and Decision Economics 15: 503–9.
Zankel, P. (1992) “Wanted: Tickets—A Reassessment of Current Ticket
Scalping Legislation and the Controversy Surrounding Its Enforcement.”
Seton Hall Journal of Sport Law 2: 129–49.
CREATING A FUTURES MARKET FOR MAJOR EVENT TICKETS
461