Introduction
e upsurge in inflation that began in 2021—the
sharpest in more than three decades—has affected
fiscal accounts, worsened poverty, and altered the
distribution of households’ well-being, calling on
policymakers to respond. is chapter analyzes these
developments and explores how fiscal policy can do its
part to curb inflation while supporting the vulnerable.
1
Most people strongly dislike high and variable
inflation,
2
which causes many distortions in the
economy (Agarwal and Kimball 2022), including greater
uncertainty. Relative prices of goods and services may
become blurred—no longer reflecting relative demand
and supply conditions and making everyday decisions
about consumption, investment, and production
decisions harder for households, financiers, and firms.
Inflation is more likely to become persistent if, akin to
a tug-of-war, each group in the economy—employers
and workers, producers and consumers, and retailers
and their suppliers—tries to hold on to its share of
prosperity at the expense of others. If such social
tensions lead to inconsistent macroeconomic policies
(for example, monetary policy that is too loose), high
inflation will persist longer, ultimately prolonging a
costly phenomenon for everyone.
Inflation often leads to a rise in poverty from
loss of purchasing power (Cardoso 1992), and,
as with any adversity, poor families tend to suffer
is chapter was prepared by staff from the Fiscal Affairs
Department. e authors of this chapter are Marcos Poplawski-
Ribeiro (team lead), Carlos Eduardo Gonçalves (team co-lead),
Chadi Abdallah, Vybhavi Balasundharam, Yongquan Cao, Daniel
Garcia-Macia, Andres Ghini, Ting Lan, Anh Dinh Minh Nguyen,
Julieth Pico Mejía, and Alberto Tumino, with research support
from Kardelen Cicek, Arika Kayastha, Zhonghao Wei, and Andrew
Womer, and under the guidance of Paolo Mauro and Paulo Medas.
1
Although the spike in prices during 2021–22 was initially
concentrated in food and energy, this chapter discusses inflation
more generally as a sustained rise in the prices of many goods
and services, which may originate from different sources. e
analysis measures inflation using the Consumer Price Index (CPI),
complementing it with the GDP deflator in specific exercises. For
recent developments on the relationship between inflation and
public finances, see also Chapter 1.
2
See survey results in Shiller (1997), Scheve (2001), and Prati (2022).
disproportionately more because they consume more
as share of their income and they lack buffers in the
form of accumulated savings. But the distributive
effects of inflation stemming from its uneven impacts
on the budgets of different households are far more
complex. In turn, these depend on various factors,
including the source of price increases (for example,
food or energy prices) and their form (demand,
or wage push); households’ consumption baskets,
sources of income, and the size and composition
of their balance sheets (for example, their position
as net borrowers or lenders); and policy design and
responses (such as indexation of wages, pensions,
and social safety nets). Government policies need to
be informed by an understanding of how inflation
affects various groups in society. Greater availability
of household data makes it possible to analyze how
big those effects are, which channels affect them, and
how they vary across households.
3
e impact of inflation on the fiscal accounts also
depends on redistribution—in this case, between the
public sector and the private sector. An unexpected
bout of inflation erodes the real (inflation-adjusted)
value of public debt, at least in the near term, with
bondholders bearing the loss. Likewise, deficit-to-GDP
ratios decline because the nominal (current monetary)
values of the economys output and of tax bases
will generally rise, generating more revenues, while
spending—often set in nominal terms in the budget—
initially fails to keep up. Without indexation, real
incomes decline for civil servants, pensioners, and
recipients of welfare transfers. e quality of public
services may also suffer as nominal spending ceilings
clash with higher costs of goods and services. e early
decline in deficits as a share of GDP may not last over
the medium term; yet, as inflation becomes expected,
spending catches up, and the cost of borrowing
rises as investors require an inflation risk premium
3
Empirical analyses of historical episodes have been constrained by
limited availability of comparable data. A study based on surveys of
overall incomes of households in Israel with at least one employee,
for the period 1950−91 (including the hyperinflation of the
mid-1980s), reports evidence of a statistically significant correlation
between inflation and inequality in incomes (Dahan 1996).
INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
CHAPTER
2
International Monetary Fund | April 2023 1
FISCAL MONITOR: ON THE PATH TO POLICY NORMALIZATION
2 International Monetary Fund | April 2023
and central bank policy rates are hiked. Initial fiscal
gains may even be reversed in some cases, notably if
growth falters.
High and volatile inflation thus makes fiscal
management more challenging, potentially
undermining the credibility of economic institutions
and of the fiscal framework. Fiscal planning and
budget preparation become more complex not only
because of uncertainty regarding prices, wages,
and interest rates but also because the overall fiscal
stance affects inflation through aggregate demand
and through inflation expectations (Coibion,
Gorodnichenko, and Weber 2021).
Governments can influence how the costs of
inflation are allocated, via indexation or discretionary
policy decisions. ey could choose, for example, to
let inflation quietly increase taxation while eroding
public pensions, wages, and transfers or instead seek
to keep the real values of these variables unchanged.
ey could also make the tax or transfer more or less
progressive by adjusting some items but not others.
Further complicating policymakers’ task, widespread
indexation of public wages and other expenditure
items would entrench inflation expectations and make
inflation more persistent. Such anticipation of inflation
makes price stability harder to achieve. Similarly, if
untargeted support outlasts spikes in energy prices or
other prices that originally motivated it, fiscal costs
and contributions to aggregate demand would be
unnecessarily prolonged (October 2022 Fiscal Monitor,
Chapter 1). High inflation can lead to policy mistakes
that may ultimately hamper investment and economic
growth, whereas price stability helps all individuals in
the economy.
Against this backdrop, it is timely to review what
we know about these variegated interactions between
inflation and fiscal variables and draw lessons for
the conduct of fiscal policy. e chapter analyzes the
following questions:
How does inflation affect fiscal accounts? And how do
the effects depend on institutional features of the tax
and benefit system, such as indexation? The section
“Impact of Inflation on Public Finances” reviews
the mechanisms through which inflation affects
public finance; surveys indexation practices across
the world; and estimates the impact of inflation on
public debts, deficits, expenditures, and revenues in
the near and medium term.
How large are the distributive effects of inflation across
households in countries at different levels of economic
and financial development, and what is the role of
fiscal policy? The section “Distributive Effects of
Inflation and Fiscal Policy Support” analyzes the
impact of inflation on poverty and the distribution
of consumption, income, and net wealth, using
household surveys for six countries at different levels
of economic and financial development.
What is the role of fiscal policy in the efforts to
promote price stability? The section “Disinflating
and Distributing” estimates the impact of fiscal
policy on inflation through aggregate demand.
Using model simulations that allow for distributive
effects, it explores how fiscal policy can support
monetary policy to curb inflation while protecting
vulnerable households.
e conclusion summarizes the chapters policy
implications.
Impact of Inflation on Public Finances
Inflation can affect fiscal aggregates through multiple
channels, with varying effects over time (Dynan 2022;
US CBO 2022a).
Direct Channels of Impact
e main direct channels through which inflation
affects public finances, abstracting from subsequent
fiscal and monetary policy reactions, are listed below
and sketched out in the Executive Summary.
Inflated nominal values for GDP and the tax base.
Higher nominal output lowers debt and deficits as
a share of GDP. The nominal tax base also grows
with inflation. For example, more revenues from
value-added taxes are collected as the prices of
underlying goods and services go up. For some
taxes, such as income taxes, revenues may increase
even more than one-for-one with inflation,
including because some taxpayers may jump over
nominal thresholds to higher tax brackets (bracket
creep).
4
These effects also depend on the degree of
4
Beer, Griffiths, and Klemm (2023) analyze further channels
through which inflation affects the real value of collected tax
revenues, including the erosion of such revenues if inflation is high
and they are collected with a lag (Tanzi 1977).
CHAPTER 2 INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
3International Monetary Fund | April 2023
indexation (in this case, of thresholds), discussed
later in the chapter.
Inertia in nominal spending. The net response
of the fiscal balances to inflation depends on
whether expenditure keeps pace with revenues.
During the budget year, this is seldom the case
because spending caps are usually set in nominal
terms, although indexation of some important
items such as public wages and transfers may
lead in some cases to automatic adjustments to
inflation in the same year. Ad hoc adjustments
or new measures such as introduction or
enhancement of subsidies (for example, in
response to higher food or energy prices) can also
speed up the rise in nominal spending.
Sovereign debt size and structure, and investors
response. The larger the debt, the greater the
potential erosion from inflation. This effect is
attenuated, however, if a portion of the debt is
inflation-linked (as inflation automatically leads
to higher borrowing costs), is denominated in
foreign currency (as inflation leads to depreciation,
potentially resulting in higher repayments when
expressed in domestic currency), has a floating
rate (as inflation prompts higher policy, and
hence higher short-term benchmark rates), or
has a greater share of short-term bonds that are
maturing and need to be rolled over (as investors
will ask for higher rates on newly issued bonds).
When governments issue new debt, investors may
require higher returns to compensate not only for
expected inflation but also for higher inflation
volatility (an inflation risk premium)—and, for
countries where economic prospects are uncertain
and the debt ratio remains high or keeps rising, a
default premium.
International Practices with Inflation Indexation
Countries’ practices vary regarding how much tax
or budget items are indexed to inflation or adjusted
to inflation by policy measures. is has consequences
for how their public finances evolve in the face of
inflation surprises. Indexation of politically salient
expenditure items such as pensions or wages is often
a prominent topic in public discourse. e effects
on the revenue side, while less discussed, are no less
relevant. If income tax thresholds are not adjusted to
inflation, for example, taxpayers may be pushed into
higher tax brackets (bracket creep), or the value of
their tax allowances and deductions may be eroded.
e degree of indexation involves trade-offs. On
one hand, indexing public wages, pensions, or welfare
transfers reduces uncertainty and preserves purchasing
power for civil servants, retirees, and low-income
households. It may also prevent distortionary gaps
between public and private wages or a possible brain
drain from the public sector. On the other hand,
indexation sustains real expenditures, contributing to
aggregate demand and potentially making inflation
more persistent. If public wages are a benchmark for
private wages (as in many countries), indexation of
public wages could prolong wage and inflationary
pressures (Box 2.1). Widespread indexation can limit
the scope for discretionary cuts.
Countries have taken different approaches to
indexation policies (Figure 2.1). A minority of
countries index or regularly adjust their income tax
rate brackets to minimize bracket creep.
Indexation is more common for some important
expenditure items, especially pensions. Nearly all
advanced economies, about 50 percent of emerging
market economies, and 30 percent of low-income
developing countries have some form of indexation.
Pension indexation has become more prevalent
recently, but many countries have made it less generous
to reduce the burden on the budget and safeguard
the sustainability of pension systems (OECD 2022a).
Countries have moved from wage indexation toward
price indexation as nominal wage increases have
tended to exceed price inflation in the past, reflecting
productivity gains.
5
Many countries further index
their social assistance programs, with around half of
advanced economies linking several of their benefits to
inflation (OECD 2022c). By contrast, most countries
do not index public wages to inflation—a practice that
has become less prevalent in recent decades, perhaps
because inflation had been low. But the pressure
to index wages may return if high inflation persists
(Suthaharan and Bleakley 2022).
6
5
In 2022, such a strategy may have been costlier than predicted
given that inflation rose faster than nominal wages (OECD 2022d).
6
For public wages, their increases in most countries tend to be
related to the political cycle rather than to indexation (Gaspar,
Gupta, and Mulas-Granados 2017).
FISCAL MONITOR: ON THE PATH TO POLICY NORMALIZATION
4 International Monetary Fund | April 2023
Effects of Inflation on Public Finances over
the Medium Term
Inflation surprises often improve debt and budget
balances in the near term, but are these gains
maintained over the medium term? To answer this
question, the chapter employs both quarterly and
annual data.
7
e effects of inflation on public finance
could ebb over time for three main reasons. First,
7
Recent attempts to answer this question have used different
methods, including event studies (Blanco, Ottonello, and Ranosova
2022), model-based simulations (Bénassy-Quéré 2022), and surprises
in World Economic Outlook forecasts (October 2022 Fiscal Monitor,
Chapter 1). e US Congressional Budget Offices 2002 workbook
allows users to simulate alternative economic scenarios by specifying
different values for inflation (and three other economic variables) for
the United States, comparing them to its baseline projections (US
CBO 2022b). e estimates in this section use the local projection
method (Jordà 2005). e annual historical data include many more
(emerging market) economies, allowing the research of samples where
inflation is higher, more volatile, and less surprising (more persistent).
Quarterly data provide more accurate estimates of the immediate
effects of CPI inflation on fiscal variables. See Online Annex 2.2.
public spending could catch up with revenues through
indexation. Second, public policies and decisions,
including for wages or pensions, could lead to higher
spending over time, reducing any initial gains for public
finance indicators. ird, most central banks have the
statutory objective of maintaining price stability, using
adjustments in their policy rates to do so, which may
lead to a tightening of financial conditions for agents in
the economy, including the government. Even so, the
adjustment of interest expense may be gradual if the
structure of public debt is mostly in its own currency
and in long maturities and if the country’s monetary
authority has a reputation for maintaining price stability.
In such cases, exchange rate risks may be muted and
market expectations well anchored. A debt structure
with longer maturities will facilitate less pass-through of
interest rates to increases in public interest payments in
the medium term.
Analysis using historical annual data (1962−2019)
for 85 economies shows that, on average, spikes in
No regular adjustments
Regular de facto adjustments
Automatic price adjustments
Price
Wage
Mixed No
No
Yes, to other variables
Yes, to inflation
No
Yes, to other variables
Yes, to inflation
Figure 2.1. Indexation Policies Vary across the World and across Budget Items
(Percentage of countries in each income group)
1. Personal Income Tax
Brackets’ Indexation
1
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
AEs EMs LIDCs
2. Pension Indexation
2
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
AEs EMs LIDCs
3. Social Assistance Program
Indexation
3
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
AEs EMs LIDCs
4. Public Wages Indexation
4
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
AEs EMs LIDCs
Sources: IMF staff analysis based on an IMF survey and using ad
ditional data from Beer, Griffiths, and Klemm (2023); IMF Pay Sy
stems database (2016); International Social
Security Association database; OECD (2022c); and US Social Secu
rity Administration databases.
Note: Panels include data for 2016–23. Observations vary from 1
16 to 176 countries in each panel (see Online Annex 2.1 for details). Price indexation includes different
measures of inflation, for example, “core,” or measures that inc
lude only urban workers or exclude fuel, tobacco, alcohol, and others. Even with automatic indexation,
discretionary approval stages may be part of the framework that
result in ad hoc adjustments. AEs = advanced economies; EMs = emerging market economies;
LIDCs = low-income
developing countries.
1
“Regular de facto adjustments” means that personal income tax thresholds are regularly revised but not automatically.
2
“Mixed” indexation refers to an adjustment that includes a mix of price, wages, and other variables.
3
Social assistance programs include major fixed cash transfer programs. “Yes” means that majority of benefits are indexed in the country.
4
“No” means that inflation does not play an automatic or mandatory role in the setting of public wages. Indexation includes both partial and full indexation.
CHAPTER 2 INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
5International Monetary Fund | April 2023
the growth of the GDP deflator tend to reduce the
debt-to-GDP ratio persistently (Figure 2.2).
8
e drop
in the debt-to-GDP ratio is larger in economies with
higher initial debt, as expected, with an initial spike of
1 percentage point in the growth of the GDP deflator
9
associated with a persistent cumulative decline in the
debt ratio of 0.6 percentage point of GDP (see also
Chapter 1 for recent developments on the relationship
between inflation and debt). e reduction in the debt
ratio is caused by a hike in the GDP denominator and
an initial rise in fiscal balances. e debt and fiscal
balance reactions to a spike in the growth of the GDP
deflator are similar between advanced and emerging
market economies. Yet the drop in debt is significantly
smaller in countries with flexible exchange rates, as
in those countries, inflation tends to be associated
with exchange rate depreciation, increasing the value
of foreign-currency-denominated debt relative to
domestic GDP (see Online Annex 2.2).
8
e result is qualitatively robust to the use of CPI inflation.
To capture inflation from all sources, the estimates employ ordinary
least squares regressions (panels with fixed effects). e analysis
excludes countries with 2019 population of less than 1 million.
9
roughout the chapter, a “spike” in inflation refers to a sudden
rise in inflation followed by a gradual decline. Specifically, when
using annual data, a spike is a 1 percentage point increase in the
GDP deflator growth rate, followed by gradual decline in subsequent
years (see Online Annex Figure 2.2.1). When using quarterly data,
the spike in CPI inflation stems from a 1 percentage point increase
in commodity import inflation (weighted by GDP), with CPI
inflation petering out after three quarters (see Figure 2.4, panel 1).
Whereas unexpected spikes in inflation reduce the
debt ratio, increases in inflation expectations do not. e
latter are associated with a faster rise in both primary
spending and interest expense, and a smaller increase in
the nominal GDP denominator. e difference in the
effects of surprise versus expected inflation is larger for
countries with high initial debt levels (Figure 2.3). Both
results underscore that attempting to inflate public debt
away is neither a desirable nor a sustainable strategy.
If inflation surprises frequently, agents will adjust
their inflation expectations accordingly and demand
protection against it, leading to higher spreads owing to
the inflation risk.
Estimates using quarterly data from the first quarter
of 1999 to the fourth quarter of 2019 for 28 advanced
economies confirm that CPI inflation spikes tended
to improve the overall and primary fiscal balances in
the short term (Figure 2.4).
10
High-frequency data
capture the immediate effects of inflation on public
10
Regressions with quarterly data are estimated using
instrumental variables. CPI inflation spikes are instrumented by
the change in the price growth of the commodity import basket,
also interacted with an exchange rate peg dummy (lagged).
Commodity price spikes tend to be more surprising and tend to
pass through to prices of various goods and services (see Choi
and others 2018). e correlation is clear for countries with more
flexible exchange rate regimes. For these countries, commodity
import price rises tend to lead to exchange rate depreciations and
so to more inflation. is approach implies that results capture
mainly the impact of imported inflation shocks, which may differ
from domestically driven shocks affecting the GDP deflator more
directly. See Online Annex 2.2 for details.
Debt/GDP > 50 percent
Debt/GDP ≤ 50 percent
All countries in the sample
Figure 2.2. Reaction to a 1 Percentage Point Growth Spike in the GDP Deflator
(Percent of GDP)
1. Debt
–1.2
–0.8
–0.4
0.0
0.4
–1 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year after shock
2. Overall Balance
–1.2
–0.8
–0.4
0.0
0.4
–1 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year after shock
Source: IMF staff estimates using data from the IMF Public Finances in Modern History and World Economic Outlook databases.
Note: The data cover the period 1962–2019. Fixed effects ordina
ry least squares regressions use the GDP deflator as the inflation indicator and include 85 countries.
Countries with populations of less than 1 million in 2019 are e
xcluded as well as observations with annual GDP deflator inflatio
n higher than 30 percent in absolute terms or
for which the original data source changes. The panels plot the
average impulse response and the 90 percent confidence bands, with standard errors clustered at the
country level. Average debt to GDP in the sample is approximately 50 percent. See Online Annex 2.2.
FISCAL MONITOR: ON THE PATH TO POLICY NORMALIZATION
6 International Monetary Fund | April 2023
Debt/GDP > 50 percent
Debt/GDP ≤ 50 percent
Figure 2.3. Debt Reaction to Surprise versus Expected Growth Spikes in the GDP Deflator
(Percent of GDP)
–1.2
–0.6
0.0
0.6
1.2
–1.2
–0.6
0.0
0.6
1.2
1. Surprise 2. Expected
–1 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year after shock
–1 0 1 2 3 4 5
Year after shock
Source: IMF staff estimates using data from the IMF Public Finances in Modern History and World Economic Outlook databases.
Note: Fixed effects ordinary least squares regressions include 85 countries during the period with available data 1992–2019. Countries with population of less than 1 million
in 2019 are excluded as well as observations with annual surpri
se or expected inflation higher than 30 percent in absolute terms or for which the original data source
changes. Expected inflation is defined as the one-year-ahead fore
cast; surprise inflation is realized minus expected inflation. The panels plot the average impulse response
and the 90 percent confidence bands (blue shaded areas and red short-dashed lines), with standard errors clustered at the country level. See Online Annex 2.2 for details.
–1.2
–0.8
0.0
–0.4
0.4
0.8
1.2
–1.2
–0.8
0.0
–0.4
0.4
0.8
1.2
–1.2
–0.8
0.0
–0.4
0.4
0.8
1.2
1. CPI Inflation
(Percent)
2. Overall Balance 3. Total Tax Revenue
–1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 –1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Quarter after shock Quarter after shock
–1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Quarter after shock
–1.2
–0.8
0.0
–0.4
0.4
0.8
1.2
–0.6
–0.4
0.0
–0.2
0.2
0.4
0.6
–0.6
–0.4
0.0
–0.2
0.2
0.4
0.6
4. Primary Expenditure 5. Interest Expense 6. Nominal Long-Term Bond Rate
(Percent)
–1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Quarter after shock
–1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Quarter after shock
–1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Quarter after shock
Sources: IMF staff estimates using data from Gruss and Kebhaj (2019); Ilzetzki, Reinhart, and Rogoff (2019); and IMF Internatio
nal Financial Statistics and World Economic
Outlook databases.
Note: Regressions are estimated between the first quarter of 199
9 and the fourth quarter of 2019 using instrumental variables a
nd control for quarter indicator variables and
country and year fixed effects (fixed effects two-stage least squ
ares). The panels plot the average impulse response and the 90 percent confidence bands (blue shaded
area) with standard errors clustered at the country level. See Online Annex 2.2 for details. CPI = Consumer Price Index.
Figure 2.4. Estimated Initial Gains to Fiscal Balances from CPI Inflation Spikes
(Percent of GDP, unless stated otherwise)
CHAPTER 2 INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
7International Monetary Fund | April 2023
finance before policies have time to react. e findings
suggest that for each 1 percentage point initial increase
in inflation, budget balances go up by 0.5 percent
of GDP. Revenue broadly rises in line with nominal
GDP, whereas primary expenditures tend to be stable
in nominal terms in initial quarters. Interest expense
climbs gradually over time given that debt in the
sample features mainly fixed rates and long maturities,
slowing the pickup in effective nominal rates of
public bonds.
e quarterly data further enable empirical
exercises for budget subcomponents, revealing
different patterns among them (see Online
Annex 2.2). While total tax revenue in nominal
terms grows by about the same magnitude as
inflation, some items (profit and income taxes)
rise proportionally more. On the expenditure side,
some expenditure categories are sticky, especially
compensation of employees and social benefits. Over
time, automatic or de facto indexation brings those
expenditures back to their initial levels in real terms.
Distributive Effects of Inflation and
Fiscal Policy Support
Beyond the overall impact of inflation on the
fiscal accounts, analyzing the effects of inflation on
the distribution of households’ well-being is key
to understanding how policies, including social
protection, can be designed to take such effects into
consideration. Such an analysis can also be useful
for exploring the political feasibility of other policies
or reforms by identifying potential pressure points
(relative winners and losers among those who stand
to gain or lose from inflation). As the discussion that
follows shows, for example, the impact of inflation
in countries with sizable mortgage markets is more
adverse—as a share of household income—for those
older than age 65 (usually net holders of nominal
assets) than for people in their 30s to 40s (who often
have mortgage debt outstanding). When considering
the design, timing, and preparatory work for reforms
to pensions or health care, it would be helpful to
consider that inflation is already placing a burden
on the households and groups that would be more
affected. is section uses household-level data for
distinct countries and economic groups to examine
such distributive effects.
Channels for Distributive Effects of Inflation
across Households
Inflation affects the distribution of households
well-being through three main channels:
11
Differences in price increases across goods combined
with differing consumption patterns (consumption
basket channel). If the prices of some goods rise
more than those of others, households with a higher
share of higher-priced goods in their consumption
baskets will suffer more. For example, spikes in food
prices may hurt the consumption of the poor more
than other households because food constitutes a
larger share of consumption (and income) for the
poor (Baez Ramirez, Inan, and Nebiler 2021). If
inflation becomes equally widespread across goods
and services, this differential effect abates.
Impact on households’ real incomes (income channel).
Real incomes may be significantly eroded if wages,
pensions, or other transfers do not keep pace with
inflation. The extent and distribution of such erosion
depends not only on features of the labor market and
pension or transfer systems but also on the source of
price changes. During the price surge of 2021, which
was driven by commodity prices, for example, real
wages fell in most commodity-importing countries
but rose in some commodity-exporting countries.
In some historical episodes during which inflation
originated from a worker-led push for compensation,
real wages may have risen.
12
Moreover, if price and
wage changes stem from the sudden emergence
of imbalances in demand and supply for certain
sectors or skills, some workers may benefit (or be
harmed) disproportionately. Likewise, wage and
pension indexation may serve some workers or
retirees to the detriment of others (Süssmuth and
Wieschemeyer 2022).
Impact on the real value of households’ initial stock
of assets and liabilities (wealth channel). Inflation
is expected to lead to a change in relative asset
prices and a reduction in real terms of households
11
See also Online Annex 2.3 and Cardoso and others (2022). e
term “well-being” is a shorthand for the sum of these three effects.
e analysis does not estimate welfare using utility functions, nor
does it consider households’ behavioral responses.
12
According to Hirschman (1985, 60), the experience in Argentina
in 1946–55 could be interpreted as an attempt at redistribution
toward lower-income groups through higher wages, social security,
and transfers, which were also associated with higher inflation.
FISCAL MONITOR: ON THE PATH TO POLICY NORMALIZATION
8 International Monetary Fund | April 2023
initial liabilities. A surprise hike in inflation in
principle helps net borrowers and hurts net lenders
(Doepke and Schneider 2006). In countries featuring
developed financial and credit markets, wealth effects
are potentially relevant. The change in relative asset
prices means that portfolio composition also matters.
Families holding cash as their main asset tend to be hit
the most (Albanesi 2007). Likewise, holders of bank
deposits and fixed-rate government bonds usually
incur real losses from inflation. Instead, historically,
home or land ownership has served as good protection
against inflation, and mortgage borrowers have often
benefited from it (Box 2.2).
Estimation
e effects through these three channels are
estimated for six economies, using a new rich set
of statistics and household survey data. e sample
encompasses low-income and developing countries
(Kenya and Senegal ), emerging market economies
(Colombia and Mexico), and advanced economies
(Finland and France). ese countries also vary with
respect to past inflation histories, status as commodity
exporters or importers, and availability and use of
mortgage and other household credit markets. e
wealth channel is estimated only for Colombia,
Finland, and France, given data constraints.
To illustrate, the analysis focuses on observed
price developments during the initial upsurge in
global prices in the aftermath of the COVID-19
pandemic; that is, the second quarter of 2021 to the
second quarter of 2022. is rise was concentrated
in food and energy prices and was associated with a
cost-of-living crisis for millions of people across the
world. All countries in the sample faced significant
headline inflation, ranging from 6.1 percent in
France to 9.2 percent in Colombia during the period
considered. Prices of food spiked the least in Finland
and France, whereas energy prices in those countries
rose the most (Online Annex 2.3).
13
e consumption basket channel is illustrated by
reporting averages, by quintile, of household-specific
inflation and the contributions of various
components of household consumption baskets
(food and nonalcoholic beverages; housing, water,
13
See Online Annex 2.3 for the details, including the assumptions
for the income and wealth estimates. Online Annex 2.3 further
analyzes total net wealth, including real assets, such as dwellings.
electricity, gas, and other fuels; transportation; other)
for the second quarter of 2021 to the second quarter
of 2022 (Figure 2.5). A household’s specific inflation
is the weighted average of the percentage price
hikes (in each country) for each given consumption
category, with the weights derived from the individual
household’s consumption basket as reported in
the survey.
Household-specific inflation levels are higher for
households in lower income quintiles in Colombia,
Kenya, Mexico, and Senegal, reflecting a larger
contribution from food price increases for the lower
quintiles (Figure 2.5). In turn, this stemmed from a
combination of (1) more rapid increases in food prices
than in other goods and (2) the well-known universal
pattern whereby the share of food in total consumption
declines with income per person.
14
For Finland and
France, household-specific inflation rates are nearly the
same across income quintiles. In these two countries,
the contribution from food prices was limited because
the rise in food prices was less pronounced, and food
accounts for a share of consumption that is lower and
roughly the same across quintiles. Energy prices rose
faster and account for a sizable portion of the overall
increase, although the effect was felt through utilities
at the lower quintiles and transportation (which
includes fuel) at the higher quintiles.
15
More recently,
energy prices have adjusted down to levels seen before
Russia’s invasion of Ukraine (see Chapter 1), and these
consumption basket channels may abate or even reverse.
However, as found in new evidence reported in Box 2.3,
changes in relative prices can on occasion persist or
widen for several years, with meaningful implications for
the budgets of different groups.
Although the effects occurring through the
consumption basket channel were sizable during the
period analyzed, they may become negligible (or
reverse) when other sample periods are considered that
14
In developing or emerging market economies such as
Colombia, Kenya, Mexico, and Senegal, the poorest households
spend 40–50 percent of their budget on food, compared with
15–30 percent for their richest quintiles. In advanced economies
such as Finland and France, the budget share spent on food is
roughly constant across quintiles at 10–15 percent. In the United
States too, transportation represents a large expenditure share for the
middle/upper class (e Economist 2023).
15
Whereas energy used for utilities in these countries is a larger
share of consumption for lower-income households, the share of
transportation in total consumption rises with household income
(see Hellebrandt and Mauro 2015 for international evidence).
CHAPTER 2 INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
9International Monetary Fund | April 2023
encompass, for example, food price increases similar to
(or lower than) the general price index.
16
Whereas the consumption basket channel
appropriately received much attention in several
recent analyses,
17
the other two channels often have
had even greater impacts. e income channel was
generally the most prominent, but its sign differed
across countries (Figure 2.6, blue bars).
18
In Finland,
France, Kenya, and Senegal, nominal changes in
remuneration of families through wages, pensions,
16
In all countries except Finland, the consumption channel is
negative at the bottom of the income distribution and positive at the
top. e finding confirms the evidence shown above on the cost of
living in Colombia, Kenya, Mexico, and Senegal increasing more for
poor households than for rich households.
17
See, for example, OECD (2022b) for Organisation
for Economic Co-operation and Development economies;
Charalampakis and others (2022), Claeys and Guetta-Jeanrenaud
(2022), and Mohrle and Wollmershauser (2021) for European
countries; and Autor, Dube, and McGrew (forthcoming), Jaravel
(2022), and US CBO (2022c) for the United States.
18
Figure 2.6 assumes changes in nominal values of incomes, assets,
and liabilities in line with the data discussed in Online Annex 2.3.
e annex includes another simulation in which those financial
resources are assumed to remain constant in nominal terms, allowing
for a study of the immediate effects of an unexpected inflationary
shock. In that scenario, the total immediate effects of inflation on
households’ incomes are negative in all countries, with the fall in real
income being equal to the level of inflation.
and other income failed to keep pace with price
hikes. In Colombia and Mexico, real incomes rose. e
fact that these two countries are oil exporters may
explain why nominal income increased there more
recently. Institutional factors may be at play too—for
example, wage and pension indexation is widespread
in Colombia and Mexico. In most countries, the
impact of inflation via this channel did not vary
much across quintiles and, to the extent it did, there
was no clear pattern, with several characteristics
playing important roles (including the gender of the
head of household; Mao 2022).
Effects occurring through the wealth channel are
also significant in the countries for which data are
available (Figure 2.6, green bars) and present the most
complex interactions with household income, age
of the head of the household, and country-specific
mortgage and household credit markets.
19
In Finland
and France, real losses from the erosion of net nominal
assets (or gains from erosion of net nominal liabilities)
19
Emerging market and advanced economies generally have
more developed financial markets and higher household debt levels
(Bahadir and Gumus 2016; Jordà, Schularick, and Taylor 2016).
Credit for large real assets, such as dwellings, is less widespread in
low-income countries. For an analysis of the penetration of mortgage
loans in those economies, see Badev and others (2014).
Other consumption categories
Transport Housing, water, electricity, gas, and other fuels Food and nonalcoholic beverages Annual inflation
1. Kenya
0
2
4
6
8
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
2. Mexico
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
3. Senegal
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
4. Colombia
0
2
4
6
8
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
5. Finland
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
6. France
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
21 to the second quarter of 2022. In Colombia and Mexico, and in Finland and France, quintiles are built
FISCAL MONITOR: ON THE PATH TO POLICY NORMALIZATION
10 International Monetary Fund | April 2023
differ significantly across household income groups.
Families in the fourth quintile in Finland and the
third and fourth quintiles in France are, on average,
net borrowers (at least in terms of liquid assets and
liabilities) and thus experience net wealth gains from
inflation.
20
Conversely, families in the two lowest
quintiles in Finland and, to a lesser extent, those in the
lowest and highest quintiles in France are net lenders
(or holders of net nominal assets) and experience
losses. In Colombia, households for all income groups
report, on average, that they have net liquid liability
positions.
21
e positive size of the wealth effect is
significant, in comparison with the other effects, and
does not present a straightforward association with
income—the largest gains are for the lowest and
highest income quintiles.
20
e conclusions may depend on whether real assets, including
dwellings, are considered (see Online Annex 2.3).
21
Although this would merit further analysis, the asset counterpart
to these positions could be with financial institutions (including
informal ones). e survey does not include information about
ownership of these assets.
Considering the overall impact of inflation and the
relative importance of the three channels (consumption
basket, income, and wealth) in different countries and
for different income groups, it becomes apparent that
the impact of inflation on well-being is variegated and
depends on several factors. In Kenya, during the period
considered, the impact of inflation was worse the lower
the income group, largely owing to the stronger impact
of food prices on the poor. e pattern is similar,
though less pronounced, in Mexico, whereas in Senegal,
the income channel drove most of the action, with
little variation across quintiles. In Colombia, the overall
impact of inflation was similar across income quintiles,
as the income and wealth channels masked the pattern
stemming from the consumption basket channel. In
Finland and France, the middle quintiles were less
affected than the highest and lowest. While the income
channel was the most sizable, variation across quintiles
reflected the wealth channel.
22
22
For inequality trends by income percentile in the United States
caused by inflation see Autor, Dube, and McGrew (forthcoming).
Income Consumption Total Income Consumption Total Income Consumption Total
Income
Wealth
Consumption
Total
Income
Wealth
Consumption
Total
Income
Wealth
Consumption
Total
Figure 2.6. Income, Consumption, and Wealth Channels, 2021−22
(Percent of household income)
1. Kenya
–8
–6
–4
–2
0
2
4
6
8
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
2. Mexico
–8
–6
–4
–2
0
2
4
6
8
–8
–6
–4
–2
0
2
4
6
8
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
3. Senegal
–8
–6
–4
–2
0
2
4
6
8
–8
–6
–4
–2
0
2
4
6
8
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
4. Colombia
–8
–6
–4
–2
0
2
4
6
8
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
5. Finland
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
6. France
Poorest 2 3 4 Richest
Source: IMF staff calculations, as described in Online Annex 2.3.
Note: The figure covers the period from the second quarter of 20
21 to the second quarter of 2022. For Colombia, results are based on the financial inclusion module of the
Great Integrated Household Survey (GEIH) to include the wealth effect. Results for income and consumption basket channels using a representative survey are similar.
CHAPTER 2 INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
11International Monetary Fund | April 2023
Redistributive wealth effects of inflation are
also strongly influenced by the age of the head of
household, especially in countries with sizable markets
for mortgages. Figure 2.7 shows that for Finland and
France, young families, which tend to be net borrowers
(for example, via mortgages), experience gains through
the wealth channel. For most families, a mortgage is
the largest loan they ever undertake to gain ownership
of their largest asset—their home. In contrast, older
age groups, which typically do not have mortgages
and are net holders of nominal assets, experience
wealth erosion. is pattern holds within each income
quintile and in these countries is most pronounced
within the highest income quintile, which has the
easiest access to credit and asset markets. No clear
pattern is identified in Colombia, however. To sum
up, in advanced economies, a group highly exposed
to losses from inflation would consist of retirees who
live in a rental apartment and hold their savings in
nominal assets and whose pension is not indexed.
e importance of age is further corroborated
by results for Spain by Cardoso and others (2022).
Table 2.1 compares their results with those in
this chapter.
Poverty
e analysis further suggests a likely increase in
poverty in all economies analyzed. Figure 2.8 displays
the change in absolute poverty headcount following four
Poorest
p20–p40 p40–p60 p60–p80 Richest
–9
–6
–3
0
3
6
9
12
–21
–18
–15
–12
–9
–6
–3
0
3
6
9
12
–21
–18
–15
–12
–9
–6
–3
0
3
6
9
12
<36 36–45 46–55 56–65 >65
Age of the head of household
<36 36–45 46–55 56–65 >65
Age of the head of household
<36 36–45 46–55 56–65 >65
Age of the head of household
1. Colombia 2. Finland 3. France
21 to the second quarter of 2022. Each line in the panels corresponds to the income brackets. The wealth
e net borrowers, whereas elderly people tend to be net lenders. Therefore, the wealth effect is usually
Table 2.1. Total Effect of Inflation on Saving Capacity by Age-Income Groups
(Percent of household income)
Age
Spain Colombia Finland France
Income Quartile Income Quintile Income Quintile Income Quintile
Poorest Second Third Richest Poorest Second Third Fourth Richest Poorest Second Third Fourth Richest Poorest Second Third Fourth Richest
<36 –2.6 –2.9 –2.4 –2.9 9.0 –8.4 –8.1 –7.4 –7.7 –6.2 –6.1 –2.8 0.1 1.6 –5.1 –3.1 0.2 0.9 6.0
36–45 –0.9 –0.3 –1.0 –2.0 –3.4 –8.0 –7.2 –7.1 –5.0 –5.8 –5.5 –3.7 –1.7 –0.7 –4.3 –3.0 –1.2 0.1 5.0
46–55 –3.5 –3.5 –3.9 –4.4 –0.7 –8.5 –8.2 –7.5 –5.7 –3.3 –6.0 –6.6 –5.3 –4.9 –5.2 –4.1 –3.7 –3.8 –2.9
56–65 –8.3 –6.2 –6.9 –6.8 –10.1 –7.6 –8.1 –7.6 –6.2 –10.4 –9.3 –8.7 –9.3 –12.9 –7.8 –6.9 –7.3 –7.1 –8.9
>65 –12.7 –9.6 –9.8 –9.7 –11.3 –13.0 –9.1 –8.4 –7.8 –17.3 –16.9 –18.2 –18.2 –27.0 –11.2 –10.4 –10.4 –11.2 –18.5
Sources: Cardoso and others (2022) for Spain and IMF staff calculations for Colombia, Finland, and France.
Note: Age brackets are based on the age of the head of household. See Online Annex 2.3 for details.
FISCAL MONITOR: ON THE PATH TO POLICY NORMALIZATION
12 International Monetary Fund | April 2023
scenarios of price hikes:
23
(1) baseline or actual inflation
(and distribution across goods and services) in each
country from the second quarter of 2021 to the second
quarter of 2022, (2) an average or widespread price hike
in all goods and services, whose increase remains equal
to the country’s inflation level, (3) a 5 percent hike in
the price of food and nonalcoholic beverages on top of
observed price rises, and (4) a 5 percent spike in energy
prices on top of observed price rises.
e estimated impact of inflation (observed baseline)
on the poverty rate, prior to new compensatory
measures, is as high as about 1 percentage point in
France, Mexico, and Senegal. Such increases in poverty
already consider the growth of nominal income, which
helped contain the adverse effects of inflation on
poverty. In the countries studied, the mitigating effect
of the growth in nominal income on poverty varies,
with some countries experiencing little to no effect,
while others, like Colombia, experienced a significant
reduction in the poverty headcount (0.4 percentage
point). Rises in food prices had a disproportionate
impact on vulnerable populations during the period
23
Poverty headcount is the share of the population whose income
falls below international poverty lines set by the World Bank.
considered. e effect of a rise in food prices is larger
in Kenya, Senegal, and Mexico, whereas energy price
hikes are more important for Colombia, Finland, and
France. If the pace of increases in food and energy
prices declines below average consumer price inflation, a
significant source of increases in poverty may subside.
Disinflating and Distributing
e previous sections show how inflation affects
public finances and households. Now the analysis
turns to whether and how fiscal policy affects
inflation. Understanding the specific channels through
which public policies affect inflation and how those
policies can contribute to the mix of instruments
meant to restore price stability are two complex and
interconnected issues. Monetary and fiscal policies
have their own distributional effects. In addition, their
overall impacts on the macroeconomy vary according to
the structure of wealth and income inequality. Recent
studies (often using a so-called Heterogeneous Agent
New Keynesian [HANK] approach) have indicated that
the role played by fiscal policy in aggregate demand
and inflation management may be larger than typically
assumed. ese studies have also considered monetary
policys possible effect on distribution.
is section discusses how fiscal policy may lead to,
or may help deal with, moderately high inflation. It
does not speak to cases of instability, such as episodes
of debt distress, which currently apply to a small set of
emerging markets. Situations in which the government
does not adjust the primary balance to stabilize public
debt and central banks are less independent—both
usually associated with the economic concept of fiscal
dominance—are outside the scope of this chapter.
24
Instead, the standard assumption that central banks
pursue their objective of price stability, unhindered
by concerns about public debt, holds. Public finances
matter for inflation via their impact on aggregate
demand.
25
ey also contribute to the price stability
goal if they are aligned with monetary policy, bringing
credibility to the overall macroeconomic framework.
Hence, by taming spending, governments can help
monetary policy curb inflation at lower costs for the
24
See Leeper (1991), Sims (1994), and Cochrane (1998), who
initially developed the Fiscal eory of the Price Level.
25
Over time, such effects of fiscal policy can be offset by monetary
policy through the rise in interest rates.
Baseline inflation
Average inflation
5% higher food prices
5% higher fuel prices
Figure 2.8. Changes in Poverty from Different Types of Price
Increase Shocks (Excluding New Policy Measures
Responding to Inflation)
(Percentage points)
–0.2
0.6
0.8
2.0
0.0
0.2
0.4
1.6
1.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
Kenya SenegalColombia MexicoFranceFinland
Source: IMF staff calculations.
Note: Baseline inflation refers to household inflation calculated
based on observed
inflation from the first quarter of 2021 to the second quarter of
2022. Results can
be considered as a ceiling because the estimation does not take
into account new
measures taken by the government or households to respond to th
e effects of
inflation.
CHAPTER 2 INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
13International Monetary Fund | April 2023
overall economy (see, for example, Adrian and Gaspar
2022; and Erceg and Lindé 2012).
Fiscal policy support for monetary policy in
disinflating is important for two additional reasons.
First, monetary tightening
26
can have unwelcome
distributive effects—for example, via more expensive
credit for small firms (Alfaro, Faia, and Minoiu 2022;
Haltom 2012) and because the poor do not hold
interest-bearing assets.
27
Second, a disinflation strategy
that relies solely on monetary policy is accompanied
by real interest rates that are too high, and this can
pose a challenge for debt dynamics. Government
policies, in turn, can be more agile and contemplate
other objectives if the right fiscal tool is employed.
28
Different fiscal policies can be calibrated and used to
support the disinflation effort while mitigating the
increase in poverty and income inequality at the same
time. Monetary policy does not have the mandate to
address income inequality, nor can it be targeted in the
way that fiscal policy can.
In effect, the discussion in this chapter is
geared toward policies that can help reduce overall
inflationary pressures while providing temporary
support (preferably targeted cash transfers) to the most
vulnerable. It does not advocate the use of specific
fiscal instruments to cap specific prices. As during the
recent episode, some countries have adopted price
controls or subsidies, put the squeeze on profits of
state-owned enterprises, or cut taxes to try limit price
increases and inflation (see Chapter 1 and the October
2022 Fiscal Monitor). However, such actions can be
costly to the budget, lead to shortages and rationing,
and prove ultimately ineffective and potentially make
inflation more persistent.
26
In the analysis, monetary tightening is captured by central
banks’ hikes in interest rates. However, in the current inflationary
episode, many central banks—which have used quantitative
easing to support firms and households during the recent years
of very low interest rates and the pandemic—may also restrict
their policies through quantitative tightening. For example, some
monetary authorities may stop purchasing corporate bonds, which
was guaranteeing a supply of liquidity for some firms. Other
central banks may even consider selling a portion of the corporate
bonds they hold on their balance sheets. While those policies
may have implications for (dis)inflation, they are not considered
explicitly in this chapter’s exercises.
27
Yet low interest rates are also shown to inflate stock prices,
benefiting the rich (Auclert 2019), so a monetary tightening may
have the opposite effect, depending on country characteristics.
28
Public investment projects, for instance, have long lags of
execution that are usually higher than those of monetary policy.
Historical Evidence of the Impact of Fiscal Policy
on Inflation
To assess the effect of public spending on inflation,
as motivated by the recent spending surge, for a broad
sample of economies, an empirical analysis is pursued
using historical data from 1950 for 17 advanced
economies, for two periods: 1950–85 and 1986–2019.
e split in 1985 is aimed at dividing the sample into
an earlier period of relatively passive monetary policy in
advanced economies and a later period of more active
monetary policy that anchors inflation expectations
(see Banerjee and others 2022). e analysis focuses on
public spending given that the recent debate relates to
the large spending surge during COVID-19 (Gopinath
2022), as during the two world wars (Box 2.4).
e analysis shows that the effect of public
spending on inflation varied over time (Figure 2.9). A
1 percent-of-GDP rise in government spending in the
pre-1985 period leads to an average hike in inflation
of almost 1 percentage point in the same year, phasing
out slowly. For the post-1985 period, the same shock
leads to an average increase in inflation of roughly half
that size and, differently from the first case, it flattens
out after three to four years. Monetary policy responses
to forces pushing inflation up in both periods varied
markedly. In the earlier part of the sample, central banks
were more likely to accommodate fiscal expansions,
thus allowing for a higher pass-through from those
expansions to inflation. After 1985, central banks more
often tightened monetary policy in response to fiscal
expansions to slake their inflationary effects.
Ascertaining a causal impact of public spending
on inflation (rather than vice versa, or the impact of
a third factor on both variables) involves the same
thorny methodological challenges faced by studies that
have sought to estimate the fiscal multiplier for output
(Ramey 2019; April 2012 Fiscal Monitor, Chapter 1).
Following Ramey and Zubairy (2018), this chapter
analyzes increases in government purchases that follow
news about extra military spending in the United States.
e methodological advantage is that such news is not
caused by the economic cycle, and the only impact on
the US economy occurs through additional spending.
29
As shown in Figure 2.10, there is a clear positive effect
29
Specifically, a structural vector autoregression model is
estimated, with public spending identified by quarterly news of
additional military spending in the United States from the first
quarter of 1939 to the fourth quarter of 2015 (Ramey and Zubairy
2018). See Online Annex 2.4.
FISCAL MONITOR: ON THE PATH TO POLICY NORMALIZATION
14 International Monetary Fund | April 2023
on inflation. As the blue line in panel 1 indicates,
following the news of additional military spending,
output increases in subsequent quarters, confirming
the presence of a positive fiscal multiplier (see Online
Annex 2.4). e novel result is the response of annual
inflation: It rises and reaches the highest level in less
than one year after the spending news, with inflation
going up by an additional 0.5 percentage point
than otherwise.
Fiscal Policy and Disinflation: Lessons from an
Economic Model with Income Distribution
To illustrate and understand some of the main
consequences of varied monetary-fiscal mixes, the
analysis turns to a (simple) version of a state-of-art
class of models that include a richer description of
the households’ income and wealth distribution—the
HANK model (McKay and Reis 2016; Kaplan, Moll,
and Violante 2018; Bayer, Born, and Luetticke 2023).
Such a model allows for the impact of different types
of public policies—fiscal and monetary—on the
households’ income distribution. Specifically, the analysis
here focuses on how different forms of fiscal restraint
by the government can help monetary policy achieve
price stabilization. At the same time, their distributive
effects across households are analyzed and considered for
policy design.
e model has five crucial ingredients: (1) e
government issues short-term debt that is held mostly
by the higher-income groups; (2) when debt rises above
90 percent of GDP, taxes are gradually increased to
guarantee that debt returns to that value; (3) transfers
for lower-income people boost overall private
1986–20191950–85
1. Output
Percent
2. Inflation
Sources: IMF staff analysis using the IMF Public Finances in Modern History database; and Jordà, Schularick, and Taylor (2017).
Note: The panels plot average impulse responses and the 90 perc
ent confidence bands (shaded blue area and short-dashed lines). See Online Annex 2.4 for further details.
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Years
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Years
Percentage points
–0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
–0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
Figure 2.9. Panel Evidence of the Fiscal Policy Impact on Inflation, 1950–2019
Figure 2.10. Fiscal Policy Impact on Inflation in the United States, 1939−2015
1. Impulse Response for Output
Percent
2. Impulse Response for Inflation
Sources: IMF staff estimates using the Ramey and Zubairy (2018) database; and IMF World Economic Outlook database.
Note: The figure covers the period from the first quarter of 1939
to the fourth quarter of 2015. The panels plot the average impulse responses (solid blue line) and the
90 percent
confidence bands (blue shaded areas). See Online Annex 2.4.
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quarter after shock
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quarter after shock
Percentage points
–0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
–0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
CHAPTER 2 INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
15International Monetary Fund | April 2023
consumption because these groups consume a high
share of any extra dollar of income they receive; (4) the
central bank increases real interest rates when inflation
goes above target (specifically, the central bank follows
a so-called Taylor rule); and (5) taxes on labor income
are progressive, meaning that higher-income families pay
a higher share of their income in taxes, compared with
lower-income families.
30
Calibrating the model for the United States
(Auclert and others 2021), the analysis examines three
combinations of policies to reduce inflation: (1) an
increase in the nominal interest rate above what the
Taylor rule would suggest, with fiscal policy taking
no further action than required for a gradual return
30
In this version of model, the production function includes labor
and a productivity term but not capital.
to its debt target (90 percent); (2) untargeted fiscal
tightening—that is, a reduction in overall spending
across all budget items; and (3) targeted fiscal
tightening composed of an overall cut in spending
items while increasing transfers to families in the
lowest 10 percent of the income distribution.
In the first scenario, nominal interest rates are
raised by 250 basis points to bring inflation down by
about 2 percent in roughly two years (Figure 2.11).
Output and consumption fall throughout this period.
e poorest families cut their consumption the most
because they have no assets to draw from.
e second scenario simulates a cut in overall public
spending amounting to 1 percent of GDP while
monetary policy is also actively following a Taylor
rule. is leads again to a contraction in aggregate
demand and output, with inflation falling by a total of
Inflation
(percentage points)
Consumption
GDP
99 (richest)
90–100
65–90 35–65
10–35 1–10
1 (poorest)
Inflation
(percentage points)
Consumption
GDP (right scale)
Inflation
(percentage points)
Consumption
GDP (right scale)
Figure 2.11. Disinflating via Different Policy Tightening Options in the HANK Model
(Deviation from long-term value)
Variation in Interest Rates
(Percentage points)
1. Monetary Tightening
Impact on Inflation,
Consumption, and Output
(Percent, unless stated otherwise)
Consumption by Income Bracket Percentile
(Percent)
0 1 2 3 4 5 7 9 116 8 10 12 0 1 2 3 4 5 7 9 116 8 10 12 0 1 2 3 4 5 7 9 116 8 10
12
0 1 2 3 4 5 7 9 116 8 10
12
0 1 2 3 4 5 7 9 116 8 10
12
0 1 2 3 4 5 7 9 116 8 10 12
0 1 2 3 4 5 7 9 116 8 10 12
–1.0
–0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
–1.8
–1.2
–1.5
–0.9
–0.6
–0.3
0.0
0.3
0.6
0.9
–0.8
–0.6
–0.4
–0.2
0.0
2. Fiscal Restraint Only
0 1 2 3 4 5 7 9 116 8 10 12
0 1 2 3 4 5 7 9 116 8 10 12
–1.0
–0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
–1.8
–1.2
–1.5
–0.9
–0.6
–0.3
0.0
0.3
0.6
0.9
–0.8
–0.6
–0.4
–0.2
0.0
–2.0
–1.5
–1.0
–0.5
0.0
Quarter after shock Quarter after shock Quarter after shock
3. Fiscal Restraint with Targeted Transfers
–1.0
–0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
–1.8
–1.2
–1.5
–0.9
–0.6
–0.3
0.0
0.3
0.6
0.9
–0.8
–0.6
–0.4
–0.2
0.0
–2.0
–1.5
–1.0
–0.5
0.0
Source: IMF staff calculations based on the model calibration i
n Auclert and others (2021).
Note: See Online Annex 2.4 for details. HANK = Heterogeneous Ag
ent New Keynesian.
FISCAL MONITOR: ON THE PATH TO POLICY NORMALIZATION
16 International Monetary Fund | April 2023
2 percentage points in eight quarters (as a response the
central bank cuts interest rates, which in the real world
should be interpreted as being able to raise them by
less). e drop in aggregate demand affects everyone,
but the impact is proportionately more cushioned for
higher-income families by the decline in taxation.
In the third scenario, a fiscal tightening of the same
overall size (1 percent of GDP) but with a different
composition is simulated. While the fiscal effort in other
spending items is greater than before (by 1.5 percent of
GDP), targeted transfers to the poorest 10 percent of
families are in turn increased by 0.5 percent of GDP.
e results show that in such a scenario, both GDP and
inflation go down. But because the poor households
receiving transfers consume a high share of their extra
income, aggregate consumption decreases by less than
in the other simulations. e consumption of those
targeted households goes up with the transfers. To
summarize, a generalized fiscal contraction helps contain
inflation, with a smaller drop in private consumption
than in the monetary policy scenario, but its impact
favors higher-income groups at the expense of the
lower-income groups. ese adverse distributional effects
can be remedied if the fiscal contraction is accompanied
by a targeted transfer program.
Conclusions
e evidence presented in this chapter highlights
the pattern that inflationary surprises are historically
associated with an initial rise in fiscal balances in the
short term and a fall in public debt that often persists
into the medium term. However, expected inflation is
not associated with a fall in debt ratios, stressing that
inflating debt away is neither a desirable nor a sustainable
strategy. Unexpected inflation may offer some breathing
room for debt ratios, but attempts to keep surprising
bondholders have historically proved futile or harmful.
e impact on debt is more significant for countries with
large amounts of debt, especially when it is denominated
in local currency, long term, and unindexed. For
countries with debt exceeding 50 percent of GDP,
each 1 percentage point surprise increase in inflation is
estimated to reduce public debt by 0.6 percentage point
of GDP, with the effect lasting for several years.
Current practices on indexation vary considerably
across countries. Among budget items, pensions are
the most commonly indexed, followed by transfers to
lower-income groups and public sector wages. When
reviewing automatic or discretionary indexation going
forward, policymakers need to decide which groups
and programs to protect from income erosion while
avoiding policies that make inflation more persistent.
Policymakers should carefully assess the impact of
public wage setting during periods of high inflation,
including through indexation, on the setting of
private wages. Policymakers also need to consider
potential effects of inflation on the structure of
the tax system.
e redistributive effects of inflation on households
are more complex than usually thought. Analysis of
the recent surge in inflation highlights the importance
of changes in families’ incomes and net assets for the
distributive effect, especially in countries with more
developed financial and credit markets. Policy reforms
should consider the redistribution that inflation
drives from net lenders to net borrowers, usually
associated with old and young families, respectively.
During the period considered, the poverty rate rose by
1 percentage point or more in three countries of the
sample (France, Mexico, Senegal ).
While monetary policy is in the driver’s seat
in the battle against inflation, fiscal policy can
help. Well-targeted fiscal restraint can be designed
to support monetary policy in attaining price
stability while protecting the vulnerable from
the cost-of-living crisis. e chapter documents
the empirical association between fiscal policies
and developments in inflation. Estimates suggest
that 1 percentage point of GDP in additional
public spending resulted in higher inflation by
0.8 percentage point in a sample covering the
1950–85 period and by 0.5 percentage point
thereafter. Moreover, through an economic model
capturing income distribution, the chapter shows
that targeted fiscal restraint—involving tough policy
choices on what budget items to cut and which to
protect or expand—can bring inflation down at lower
cost to aggregate consumption and income inequality
while protecting lower-income families.
CHAPTER 2 INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
17International Monetary Fund | April 2023
This box explores the interplay between public wages,
private wages, and inflation. Public wage setting needs to
be mindful of developments in prices and private wages to
attract and retain qualified civil servants while avoiding
a wage-price spiral.
Public wage setting is important to attract and
retain qualified civil servants. At the same time, public
wage hikes can increase aggregate demand or influ-
ence wage setting in the broader economy, depending
on labor market institutions (such as the density of
unions or the degree of centralization of bargaining)
and the size of the public sector.
Applying the approach of Abdallah, Coady, and
Jirasavetakul (2023) to an expanded country sample,
this box estimates the effects of public wage spikes on
private wages over the medium term using data from
30 member countries of the Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development from the first quarter
of 1990 to the second quarter of 2022. Changes in gov-
ernment wages are assumed to be predetermined with
respect to the behavior of macroeconomic variables, as
usually identified in the literature (see Blanchard and
Perotti 2002; and Jørgensen and Ravn 2022).
e results suggest that, considering labor market
institutions and conditions, public wages may have
a significant and lasting effect on private wages and
core Consumer Price Index (CPI) inflation in the
sample (Figure 2.1.1). For countries with higher union
density and centralization of wage bargaining, the peak
responses of private wages and core CPI inflation to
spikes in public wages are 0.32 percentage point and
0.12 percentage point, respectively. ey also last for
many quarters after the spike.
Prevailing macroeconomic conditions can also mat-
ter for the transmission of government wage shocks.
For instance, workers’ bargaining power is typically
greater when labor markets are tight. Similarly, firms
may have more pricing power when aggregate demand
is strong. Figure 2.1.1 suggests that the impacts of
government wage hikes on private wages and core CPI
are significantly larger and longer-lasting when labor
markets are tighter.
e findings imply that during periods of high
inflation and tight labor markets, public wage
policy should balance the need to attract and retain
high-quality civil servants against the risk of fomenting
inflationary pressures.
Higher unionization and centralization
Lower unionization and centralization
Tighter labor markets
Less tight labor markets
30 6 9 12 15 18 21
Source: IMF staff calculations based on Abdallah, Coady, and Jirasavetakul (2023).
Note: Shaded areas and dashed lines represent the 90 percent confidence bands of the impulse responses. CPI = Consumer Price In
dex.
1. Private Wages 2. Private Wages 3. Consumer Prices 4. Consumer Prices
Figure 2.1.1. Effects of Public Wage Spikes on Private Wages and Core CPI Inflation
(Percent for the response of private wages; percentage points for core CPI)
Quarter
30 6 9 12 15 18 21
Quarter
30 6 9 12 15 18
21
Quarter
30 6 9 12 15 18 21
Quarter
–0.8
–0.6
–0.4
–0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
–0.8
–0.6
–0.4
–0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
–0.1
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
–0.1
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
Box 2.1. Does Public Wage Policy Make Inflation More Persistent?
FISCAL MONITOR: ON THE PATH TO POLICY NORMALIZATION
18 International Monetary Fund | April 2023
The box shows that middle-income families in the United
States experienced sharper rises in the cost of their con-
sumption baskets, compared with higher-income families,
not only during times of rapid inflation but also during
the past two decades more generally.
Using US Bureau of Labor Statistics Consumer
Expenditure Surveys, estimates show that prices rose
faster for goods and services that make up a large share
of the consumption baskets of US middle-income house-
holds as of 2021, confirming the findings by Cravino,
Lan, and Levchenko (2020) (Online Annex 2.3).
New analysis reveals that such a price gap for
goods and services consumed by the middle class
constitutes a longer time trend. e relative price
of the consumption basket for a middle-class family
(40th–60th income percentiles) rose by 11.7 percent
relative to the consumption basket of a higher-income
family (top fifth percentile) between 1998 and 2021
(Figure 2.3.1). Potential factors underlying this differ-
ence include product innovations and price changes in
imported goods (Cravino and Levchenko 2017; Jaravel
2019). ese divergent price paths, along with static
US middle incomes (Mishel and Bivens 2021), suggest
a widening in the purchasing power of the two groups.
This box takes a historical perspective on the redistribu-
tive effect of inflation on households’ assets and liabilities.
Some patterns of redistribution from inflation
through the net wealth channel hold true in many
historical episodes. Net holders of cash, bank deposits,
and local currency (unindexed) bonds suffer real losses,
while net borrowers (notably for fixed-rate mortgages)
gain. Moreover, stockholders lose if inflation is joined
by economic disruption. Homeowners and landowners
have usually been shielded, but public policies, such
as rent control or taxation, sometimes have partially
undone such protection.
Comparing the portfolios of different demographic
groups for a sample of more than 60,000 house-
holds in the United States, Wolff (1979) analyzed the
impact of the 1969–75 period of inflation through
the net wealth channel. e biggest gainers were
homeowners who had large mortgages. Low-income
households also gained if they had a mortgage.
Homeowners gained relative to renters, middle-aged
households gained relative to younger and older ones,
married couples gained relative to singles, and Whites
gained relative to non-Whites. Inequality of wealth
declined because lower-wealth groups had higher
debt-to-asset ratios.
But the inflation protection of homeownership can
be undone, at least in part, by government policies,
as seen in France and Germany, for example, in the
aftermath of World War I. Inflation once again hit net
holders of nominal assets hardest, but homeowners were
not unscathed. In France, rent control was severe during
both world wars. Combined with inflation, this resulted
in rents falling to one-tenth of their value in real terms
between 1913 and 1950 (Piketty 2003). Likewise, in
Germany, real estate lost one-fifth of its value during
1913–27 owing to a mix of rent regulation and taxation
(Albers, Bartels, and Schularick 2022). e only asset
that gained was land, with a strong rural-urban divide
in the effect of inflation.
Recession
Price gap
99
01
03
05
07
09
11
13
15
17
19
21
Figure 2.3.1. Inflation Differentials between
Middle- and High-Income Families
(Percentage points)
1998
2000
02
04
06
08
10
12
14
16
18
20
–2
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
Sources: IMF staff analysis based on Cravino, Lan, and
Levchenko (2020); and US Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Note: Price gap is the accumulated inflation gap since 1998
between top 5th and 40th–60th income percentiles.
Box 2.3. Price Hikes and the Middle Class in the United States
Box 2.2. Inflation Effect via the Wealth Channel during Historical Episodes
CHAPTER 2 INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
19International Monetary Fund | April 2023
This box shows that large-scale fiscal support during the
pandemic bears some similarities to war-related surges
in public spending, which were followed by sustained
inflation. Will history rhyme?
e economic impact and ensuing policy response
of the COVID-19 pandemic have been compared
with those of war periods (Dell’Ariccia and others
2020; Hall and Sargent 2022). Figure 2.4.1 shows
that the hikes in debt and public primary expenditure
in 2020 constitute one of the largest annual increases
since the 1800s.
During World War I and World War II, several
tactics were used for marketing government bonds
(Eichengreen and others 2021), including forcing
banks to buy bonds and imposing ceilings on
Treasury rates. In more recent episodes, central
banks purchased sovereign bonds in the secondary
markets to reduce deflationary pressures. Even so,
they enlarged balance sheets and raised their ratio
of sovereign bonds to total assets (Ferguson, Schaab,
and Schularick 2015; October 2020 Global Financial
Stability Report, Chapter 1). Historically, wars have
often been followed by a persistent rise in inflation
(Bonam and Smădu 2021). After World War I, prices
kept going up, reaching levels more than 70 percent
higher in the United States and more than 90 percent
higher in France, Italy, and the United Kingdom
(Figure 2.4.2).
WWII
Debt (left scale)
Primary expenditure (right scale)
Revenue (right scale)
WWI
COVID-19
WWI WWII COVID-19
Sources: IMF Public Finances in Modern History database;
and IMF staff calculations.
Note: WWI = World War I; WWII = World War II.
Figure 2.4.1. Surges in Public Expenditure,
Revenue, and Debt over a Historical Span
(Percent of GDP)
1830
40
50
60
70
80
90
1900
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
2000
10
20
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
1800
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
1900
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
2000
10
20
0
25
50
75
100
125
150
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
1. United States
2. United Kingdom
France Italy
UK US
Germany (right scale)
Germany UK
US France (right scale)
Italy (right scale)
1. WWI
0
30
60
90
120
150
WWI
0
50
100
150
200
250
1914 16 18 20
Year
2. WWII
0
15
30
45
60
75
WWII
0
100
200
300
400
500
1939 41 43 45 47
Year
Source: IMF staff analysis using the Jordà-Schularick-Taylor Macro-history Database.
Note: The lines are calculated by 100 × (ln
P
t
– In P
start-of-war
), in which P
t
is the Consumer Price Index. WWI = World War I;
WWII = World War II.
Figure 2.4.2. Price Level Rises with the World Wars
(Percent)
Box 2.4. Surges in Government Spending: A Historical Perspective
FISCAL MONITOR: ON THE PATH TO POLICY NORMALIZATION
20 International Monetary Fund | April 2023
In Austria, Germany, Hungary, and Poland, inflation
surged and turned into hyperinflation in the early
1920s and was brought down only by putting an end
to financing government spending while adjusting the
budgets into balance (Sargent 1982). During World
War II, similar price surges were also observed. After
the war, prices remained elevated in most countries,
compared with before the war. Price levels were about
50 percent higher in the United Kingdom and in the
United States and more than 200 percent higher in
France and Italy.
Some authors have suggested that differences in
fiscal policy during the COVID-19 pandemic relate
to differences in inflation (de Soyres, Santacreu,
and Young 2022). As shown in Figure 2.4.3, a
small cross-section of countries, those where real
spending grew more in the past three years, also
experienced a larger increase in core inflation
(that is, inflation excluding changes in energy and
food prices).
As noted in the chapter, surprise inflation and the
rebound in growth contributed to debt reduction in
2021 and 2022. Moderate inflation has reduced debt
in the past when combined with financial repression—
which, however, brings its own costs (Esteves and
Eichengreen 2022; Mauro and Zhou 2021).
CRI
HUN
ZAF
CZE
IRL
LTU
NOR
Figure 2.4.3. Correlation between 2022
Changes in Fiscal Policy and in Core Inflation
since 2019
(Percent)
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Core inflation differential
Source: IMF staff calculations using the World Economic
Outlook database.
Note: Blue dots represent advanced economies. Red
diamonds represent emerging market economies. Core
inflation differential = core inflation in 2022 minus core
inflation in 2019. Real primary spending differential = real
primary spending in 2022 divided by real primary spending
in 2019. Data labels in the figure use International
Organization for Standardization (ISO) country codes.
0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3
Real primary spending differential
Box 2.4 (continued)
CHAPTER 2 INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
21International Monetary Fund | April 2023
References
Abdallah, Chadi, David Coady, and La-Bhus Fah Jirasavetakul.
2023. “Public-Private Wage Differentials and Interactions
Across Countries and Time.” IMF Working Paper 23/64,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Adrian, Tobias, and Vitor Gaspar. 2022. “How Fiscal Restraint
Can Help Fight Inflation.IMFBlog, November 21. https://
www .imf .org/ en/ Blogs/ Articles/ 2022/ 11/ 21/ how -fiscal
-restraint -can -help -fight -inflation.
Agarwal, Ruchir, and Miles Kimball. 2022. How Costly Is
Inflation? Finance and Development, Analytical Series, April 7.
https:// www .imf .org/ en/ Publications/ fandd/ issues/ 2022/ 03/
Future -of -inflation -partII -Agarwal -kimball.
Albanesi, Stefania. 2007. “Inflation and Inequality.Journal of
Monetary Economics 54 (4): 1088–114.
Albers, ilo N. H., Charlotte Bartels, and Moritz Schularick.
2022. “e Distribution of Wealth in Germany, 1895–2018.
CESifo Working Paper 9739, Ifo Institute for Economic
Research, Munich.
Alfaro, Laura, Ester Faia, and Camelia Minoiu. 2022.
“Distributional Consequences of Monetary Policy across
Races: Evidence from the U.S. Credit Register.” Harvard
Business School Working Paper 22–068, Boston, MA.
Auclert, Adrien. 2019. “Monetary Policy and the
Redistribution Channel.American Economic Review
109 (6): 2333–67.
Auclert, Adrien, Bence Bardóczy, Matthew Rognlie, and Ludwig
Straub. 2021. “Using the Sequence-Space Jacobian to Solve
and Estimate Heterogeneous-Agent Models.Econometrica
89 (5): 2375–408.
Autor, David, Arindrajit Dube, and Annie McGrew.
Forthcoming. “e Unexpected Compression: Competition
at Work in the Low Wage Economy.” Massachusetts Institute
of Technology, Cambridge, MA.
Badev, Anton, orsten Beck, Ligia Vado, and Simon Walley.
2014. “Housing Finance across Countries. New Data and
Analysis.” Policy Research Working Paper 6756, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Baez Ramirez, Javier Eduardo, Osman K. Inan, and Metin
Nebiler. 2021. “Getting Real? e Uneven Burden of
Inflation across Households in Turkey.” Policy Research
Working Paper 9869, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Bahadir, Berrak, and Inci Gumus. 2016. “Credit Decomposition
and Business Cycles in Emerging Market Economies.Journal
of International Economics 103 (C): 250–62.
Banerjee, Ryan, Valerie Boctor, Aaron Mehrotra, and Fabrizio
Zampolli. 2022. “Fiscal Deficits and Inflation Risks: e Role
of Fiscal and Monetary Regimes.” BIS Working Paper 1028,
Bank for International Settlements, Basel.
Bayer, Christian, Benjamin Born, and Ralph Luetticke. 2023.
“e Liquidity Channel of Fiscal Policy.Journal of Monetary
Economics 134: 86–117.
Beer, Sebastian, Mark Griffiths, and Alexander Klemm. 2023.
“Tax Distortions from Inflation: What Are ey? How to
Deal with em?” IMF Working Paper 23/18, International
Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Bénassy-Quéré, Agnes. 2022. “Public Finances: Inflation at
Pays?” French Treasury article, July 12. Paris.
Blanchard, Olivier, and Roberto Perotti. 2002. “An Empirical
Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in
Government Spending and Taxes on Output.Quarterly
Journal of Economics 117 (4): 1329–68.
Blanco, Andrés, Pablo Ottonello, and Tereza Ranosova. 2022.
“e Dynamics of Large Inflation Surges.” NBER Working
Paper 30555, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Cambridge, MA.
Bonam, Dennis, and Andra Smădu. 2021. “e Long-Run
Effects of Pandemics on Inflation: Will is Time Be
Different?” Economic Letters 208: 110065.
Cardoso, Eliana. 1992. “Inflation and Poverty.” NBER Working
Paper 4006, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Cambridge, MA.
Cardoso, Miguel, Clodomiro Ferreira, José Miguel Leiva,
Galo Nuño, Álvaro Ortiz, Tomasa Rodrigo, and Sirenia
Vazquez. 2022. “e Heterogeneous Impact of Inflation
on Households’ Balance Sheets.” Working Paper 176, Red
Nacional de Investigadores en Economía (RedNIE), Madrid.
Charalampakis, Evangelos, Bruno Fagandini, Lukas Henkel, and
Chiara Osbat. 2022. “e Impact of the Recent Rise in Inflation
on Low-Income Households.” Box 4 in ECB Economic Bulletin,
Issue 7/2022, European Central Bank, Frankfurt.
Choi, Sangyup, Davide Furceri, Prakash Loungani, Saurabh
Mishra, and Marcos Poplawski-Ribeiro. 2018. “Oil Prices
and Inflation Dynamics: Evidence from Advanced and
Developing Economies.Journal of International Money and
Finance 82 (C): 71–96.
Claeys, Grégory, and Lionel Guetta-Jeanrenaud. 2022. “Who
Is Suffering Most from Rising Inflation?” Bruegel (blog),
February 1, Bruegel, Brussels. https:// www .bruegel .org/ blog
-post/ who -suffering -most -rising -inflation.
Cochrane, John. 1998. “A Frictionless View of US Inflation.
In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1998, vol. 13, edited by
Ben S. Bernanke and Julio J. Rotemberg. Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press, 323–84.
Coibion, Olivier, Yuriy Gorodnichenko, and Michael Weber. 2021.
“Fiscal Policy and Households’ Inflation Expectations: Evidence
from a Randomized Control Trial.” NBER Working Paper
28485, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Cravino, Javier, and Andrei A. Levchenko. 2017. “e
Distributional Consequences of Large Devaluations.
American Economic Review 107 (11): 3477–509.
Cravino, Javier, Ting Lan, and Andrei A. Levchenko. 2020. “Price
Stickiness along the Income Distribution and the Effects of
Monetary Policy.Journal of Monetary Economics 110: 19–32.
FISCAL MONITOR: ON THE PATH TO POLICY NORMALIZATION
22 International Monetary Fund | April 2023
Dahan, Momi. 1996. “e Effect of Macroeconomic Variables
on Income Distribution in Israel.Bank of Israel Economic
Review 69: 19–43.
Dell’Ariccia, Giovanni, Paolo Mauro, Antonio Spilimbergo,
and Jeromin Zettelmeyer. 2020. “Economic Policies for the
COVID-19 War.IMFBlog, April 1. https:// www .imf .org/ en/
Blogs/ Articles/ 2020/ 04/ 01/ blog040120 -economic -policies -for
-the -covid -19 -war.
de Soyres, François, Ana Maria Santacreu, and Henry Young.
2022. “Fiscal Policy and Excess Inflation during Covid-19: A
Cross-Country View.FEDS Notes, Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC, July 15. https:// doi
.org/ 10 .17016/ 2380 -7172 .3083.
Doepke, Matthias, and Martin Schneider. 2006. “Inflation and
the Redistribution of Nominal Wealth.Journal of Political
Economy 114 (6): 1069–97.
Dynan, Karen. 2022. “High Inflation and Fiscal Policy.” Peter G.
Peterson Foundation Expert Views on Inflation, Interest, and
the National Debt, New York.
Economist, e. 2023. “Inflation Usually Hits Americas Poor
Hardest. Not is Time.” February 2. https:// www .economist
.com/ graphic -detail/ 2023/ 02/ 02/ inflation -usually -hits
-americas -poor -hardest -not -this -time.
Eichengreen, Barry, Asmaa El-Ganainy, Rui Esteves, and
Kris James Mitchener. 2021. “Public Debt through the
Ages.” In Sovereign Debt: A Guide for Economists and
Practitioners, edited by S. Ali Abbas, Alex Pienkowski,
and Kenneth Rogoff. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford
University Press.
Erceg, Christopher J., and Jesper Lindé. 2012. “Fiscal
Consolidation in an Open Economy.American Economic
Review 102 (3): 186–91.
Esteves, Rui, and Barry Eichengreen. 2022. “Up and Away?
Inflation and Debt Consolidation in Historical Perspective.
CEPR Discussion Paper 17559, Center for Economic and
Policy Research, Washington, DC.
Ferguson, Niall, Andreas Schaab, and Moritz Schularick. 2015.
“Central Bank Balance Sheets: Expansion and Reduction
since 1900.” CEPR Discussion Paper 10635, Center for
Economic and Policy Research, Washington, DC.
Gaspar, Vitor, Sanjeev Gupta, and Carlos Mulas-Granados.
2017. “Fiscal Politics.” In Fiscal Politics, edited by Vitor
Gaspar, Sanjeev Gupta, and Carlos Mulas-Granados.
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 3–22.
Gopinath, Gita. 2022. “How Will the Pandemic and War Shape
Future Monetary Policy?” Remarks at the Jackson Hole
Symposium, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
https:// www .imf .org/ en/ News/ Articles/ 2022/ 08/ 26/ sp -gita
-gopinath -remarks -at -the -jackson -hole -symposium.
Gruss, Bertrand, and Suhaib Kebhaj. 2019. “Commodity Terms
of Trade: A New Database.” IMF Working Paper 19/21,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Hall, George J., and omas J. Sargent. 2022. “ree World
Wars: Fiscal-Monetary Consequences.Proceedings of the
National Academy of Sciences 119 (18): e2200349119.
Haltom, Renee. 2012. “Winners and Losers from Monetary
Policy.Richmond Fed Region Focus, Second/ird Quarter,
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Richmond, VA.
Hellebrandt, Tomas, and Paolo Mauro. 2015. “e Future of
Worldwide Income Distribution.” PIIE Working Paper Series
WP15–7, Peterson Institute for International Economics,
Washington, DC.
Hirschman, Albert O. 1985. “Reflections on the Latin American
Experience.” In e Politics of Inflation and Economic
Stagnation, edited by Leon N. Lindberg and Charles S. Maier.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 53–77.
Ilzetzki, Ethan, Carmen Reinhart, and Ken Rogoff. 2019.
“Exchange Arrangements Entering the 21st Century:
Which Anchor Will Hold?” Quarterly Journal of Economics
134 (2): 599–646.
Jaravel, Xavier. 2019. “e Unequal Gains from Product
Innovations: Evidence from the US Retail Sector.Quarterly
Journal of Economics 134 (2): 715–83.
Jaravel, Xavier. 2022. “Inflation and Inequality.” Unpublished,
London School of Economics, London.
Jordà, Òscar. 2005. “Estimation and Inference of Impulse
Responses by Local Projections.American Economic Review
95 (1): 161–82.
Jordà, Òscar, Moritz Schularick, and Alan M. Taylor. 2016.
“e Great Mortgaging: Housing Finance, Crises and
Business Cycles.Economic Policy 31 (85): 107–52.
Jordà, Òscar, Moritz Schularick, and Alan M. Taylor. 2017.
“Macrofinancial History and the New Business Cycle Facts.
In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2016, vol. 31, edited
by Martin Eichenbaum and Jonathan A Parker. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 213–63.
Jørgensen, Peter L., and Søren H. Ravn. 2022. “e Inflation
Response to Government Spending Shocks: A Fiscal Price
Puzzle?” European Economic Review 141 (C): 103982.
Kaplan, Greg, Benjamin Moll, and Giovanni L. Violante. 2018.
“Monetary Policy According to HANK.American Economic
Review 108 (3): 697–743.
Leeper, Eric. 1991. “Equilibria under ‘Active’ and ‘Passive’
Monetary and Fiscal Policies.Journal of Monetary Economics
27 (1): 129–47.
Mao, Bincheng. 2022. “Inflation Affects Women More an
Men. Civil Society Can Help.World Economic Forum (blog),
October 18. https:// www .weforum .org/ agenda/ 2022/ 10/
inflation -crisis -hits -women -harder/ .
Mauro, Paolo, and Jing Zhou. 2021. “r-g <0: Can We Sleep
More Soundly?” IMF Economic Review 69: 197–229.
McKay, Alistair, and Ricardo Reis. 2016. “e Role of
Automatic Stabilizers in the U.S. Business Cycle.
Econometrica 84 (1): 141–94.
CHAPTER 2 INFLATION AND DISINFLATION: WHAT ROLE FOR FISCAL POLICY?
23International Monetary Fund | April 2023
Mishel, Lawrence, and Josh Bivens. 2021. “Identifying the Policy
Levers Generating Wage Suppression and Wage Inequality.
Economic Policy Institute, Washington, DC.
Mohrle, Sascha, and Timo Wollmershauser. 2021. “On the
Distributional Effects of the Current High Inflation Rates.
Ifo Schnelldienst digital 16: 1–6. Ifo Institute for Economic
Research, Munich.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD). 2022a. “Pensions at a Glance 2021: OECD and
G20 Indicators.” Paris.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD). 2022b. “How Inflation Challenges Pensions.
OECD Policy Brief, Paris.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD). 2022c. “Income Support for Working-Age
Individuals and eir Families.OECD Policy Brief, Paris.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD). 2022d. “OECD Employment Outlook
2022.” Paris.
Piketty, omas. 2003. “Income Inequality in France,
1901–1998.Journal of Political Economy 111 (5): 1004–42.
Prati, Alberto. 2022. “e Well-Being Cost of Inflation
Inequalities.” CEP Discussion Paper 1870, Centre for
Economic Performance, London.
Ramey, Valerie. 2019. “Ten Years after the Financial Crisis: What
Have We Learned from the Renaissance in Fiscal Research?”
Journal of Economic Perspectives 33 (2): 89–114.
Ramey, Valerie A., and Sarah Zubairy. 2018. “Government
Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence
from US Historical Data.Journal of Political Economy 126
(2): 850–901.
Sargent, omas. 1982. “e End of Four Big Inflations.
In Inflation: Causes and Effects, edited by Robert E. Hall.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 41–98.
Scheve, Kenneth. 2001. “Public Attitudes about Inflation: A
Comparative Analysis.Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin
(Autumn): 283–94.
Shiller, Robert. 1997. “Why Do People Dislike Inflation?”
In Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy, edited by
Christina Romer and David Romer. Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research Books, 13–70.
Sims, Christopher. 1994. “A Simple Model for Study of the
Determination of the Price Level and the Interaction of
Monetary and Fiscal Policy.Economic eory 4: 381–99.
Süssmuth, Bernd, and Matthias Wieschemeyer. 2022. “Taxation
and the Distributional Impact of Inflation: e U.S. Post-War
Experience.Economic Modelling 111 (C): 105813.
Suthaharan, Neyavan, and Joanna Bleakley. 2022. “Wage-Price
Dynamics in a High-Inflation Environment: e
International Evidence.RBA Bulletin (September): 51–60.
Tanzi, Vito. 1977. “Inflation, Lags in Collection, and the Real
Value of Tax Revenue.IMF Staff Papers 24: 154–67.
US Congressional Budget Office (US CBO). 2022a. “Budgetary
Effects of Higher Inflation and Interest Rates.” Response
letter from Director Mr. Phillip L. Swagel to the Honorable
Mr. Mike Crapo, Ranking Member of the US Congress’
Committee on Finance, March 2. Washington, DC.
US Congressional Budget Office (US CBO). 2022b. “Workbook
for How Changes in Economic Conditions Might Affect
the Federal Budget: 2022 to 2032.” June. Washington, DC.
https:// www .cbo .gov/ publication/ 57980.
US Congressional Budget Office (US CBO). 2022c. “How
Inflation Has Affected Households at Different Income Levels
Since 2019.” September. Washington, DC.
Wolff, Edward N. 1979. “e Distributional Effects of the
1969–75 Inflation on Holdings of Household Wealth in
the United States.Review of Income and Wealth 25 (2):
195–207.