Contents
Chapter 1: Introduction .......................................1
Chapter 2: Canada’s experience with
inflation targeting
..............................................7
Chapter 3: Key challenges for the conduct
of monetary policy
...........................................20
Chapter 4: Lessons from a comparison
of alternative frameworks
....................................33
Chapter 5: Overview of monetary policy tools.............48
Chapter 6: Strengthening the conduct
of monetary policy
............................................65
Monetary Policy
Framework
Renewal
December 2021
Chapter 1: Introduction
Building on success
Every five years, the Bank of Canada and the Government of Canada review
and renew the agreement on Canada’s monetary policy framework. In 2021,
the country’s flexible inflation-targeting framework was renewed for another
five-year period, ending on December 31, 2026.
The Government and the Bank believe that the best contribution of monetary
policy to the well-being of Canadians is to continue to focus on price stability.
The Government and the Bank also agree that monetary policy should
continue to support maximum sustainable employment, recognizing that
maximum sustainable employment is not directly measurable and is
determined largely by non-monetary factors that can change through time.
Further, the Government and the Bank agree that because well-anchored
inflation expectations are critical to achieving both price stability and
maximum sustainable employment, the primary objective of monetary policy
is to maintain low, stable inflation over time.
Under this agreement, the Bank will continue to conduct monetary policy
aimed at keeping inflationas measured by the 12-month rate of change in
the consumer price indexat 2 percent, with an inflation-control range of
1 to 3 percent.
This agreement also articulates how the Bank can continue to use the
flexibility in its framework to manage the challenges of lower neutral interest
rates globally and uncertainty about maximum sustainable employment. As
such, it provides continuity and clarity and strengthens the framework to
reflect the realities of the world we live in.
Flexible inflation targeting has delivered low, stable and predictable inflation
since it began in 1991. This has contributed to a more stable environment in
which households and firms can make spending and investment decisions. It
has also contributed to sustained growth in output, employment and
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 2
productivity and has improved Canadians’ standard of living. The 2021
reopening of the global economy has been associated with elevated inflation
in Canada and abroad. While this is a global phenomenon, it makes
maintaining a sound framework for monetary policy in Canada all the more
important.
Every time the agreement is renewed, the Bank carefully reassesses whether
the existing monetary policy framework is the best contribution that the Bank
can make to promoting Canada’s economic and financial welfare.
The 200809 global financial crisis and the COVID-19 pandemic have had a
significant impact on the global economy and financial system, and major
trends such as shifting demographics and new digital technologies are
altering the economic landscape. Climate change and the long-term transition
to net-zero greenhouse gas emissions will drive structural change in the
Canadian and global economies. Also, there is now greater recognition,
supported by economic research, that when the benefits of economic growth
and opportunity are more evenly shared, it leads to more prosperity for the
whole economy.
1
A strong and inclusive labour market helps reduce income
inequality and supports robust demand for goods and services.
Leveraging the flexibility of the framework
These trends emphasize the importance of the flexibility inherent in Canada’s
monetary policy framework. Two of them are particularly relevant:
Neutral interest rates around the worldwhich ensure that demand is in
line with an economy’s long-run productive capacityare lower than in
the past and will likely remain low in the future. This means that central
banks will have less room to lower the policy rate in response to negative
shocks. As a result, the Bank will likely have to use other monetary policy
tools more often and may need to hold interest rates low for longer.
Major forces such as shifting demographics, technological change,
globalization and shifts in the nature of work are having profound
effects on the Canadian labour market. This means there is increased
uncertainty about the level of maximum sustainable employment. In other
words, it has become more difficult to pin down the highest level of
1 See, for example, Macklem (2021) as well as Hsieh et al. (2019) and Ostry et al. (2018).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 3
employment that the economy can sustain before inflation pressures
build.
To manage these challenges, the Bank will continue to leverage the flexibility
inherent in its framework. Specifically, when conditions warrant, the Bank will:
use a broad set of monetary policy tools, as well as the 1 to 3 percent
inflation-control range, to deal with the likelihood that the Bank’s policy
rate will be at its lowest possible level more often.
actively seek the level of maximum employment needed to sustainably
achieve the inflation target. The Bank will consider a broad set of
indicators to gauge the health of the labour market and to inform its
assessment of the economic outlook.
The Bank will use the flexibility of the 1 to 3 percent range only to an extent
that is consistent with keeping medium-term inflation expectations well
anchored at 2 percent. And the Bank will clearly explain when it is using that
flexibility.
The Bank will continue to assess financial system vulnerabilities, recognizing
that a low interest rate environment can be more prone to the development
of financial imbalances. A variety of other policy instruments, such as
macroprudential tools, are better suited than monetary policy to address
these vulnerabilities. But because monetary policy can exacerbate financial
vulnerabilities, the Bank will continue to be mindful of the risk that such
vulnerabilities can lead to worse economic outcomes down the road.
Climate change poses substantial risks to the global and Canadian economies.
While monetary policy cannot directly tackle the threats posed by climate
change, the Bank will develop the modelling tools needed to take into
account the important implications of climate change on the Canadian
economy and financial system.
Conducting a more in-depth and comprehensive
review
Past reviews of the inflation-control target agreement have included serious
consideration of some alternative frameworks. However, the Bank has not
performed a systematic comparison of a full range of alternatives since it
adopted inflation targeting. For this latest review and renewal, the Bank used
a combination of model simulations, lab experiments and public consultations
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 4
to run a “horse race” of key alternatives to inflation targeting, weighing the
pros and cons of each:
average inflation targeting
a dual mandate, targeting both inflation and employment
nominal gross domestic product (NGDP)both level and growth
targeting
price-level targeting
In this horse race, the current flexible inflation-targeting framework, along
with average inflation targeting and a dual mandate, did better than other
approaches that represent larger departures from the status quo. While
neither average inflation targeting nor a dual mandate was judged to be
better overall than the current approach, the Bank found value in some
elements of each of these two alternatives. The Bank’s research concluded
that the inflation-targeting framework is flexible enough to mimic these key
elements without the drawbacks associated with the alternative approaches.
Listening to Canadians
The Bank also significantly expanded its outreach activities to include public
consultations with Canadians and discussions with a broader set of
stakeholders and interest groups. Since the 200809 global financial crisis,
central banks have implemented extraordinary policies and used a variety of
new toolsputting central banks in the public eye more than ever. The Bank’s
recent public outreach was an important opportunity to assess the economic
environment, gather input and ensure that the Bank’s policies and decisions
reflect the views of the people it serves. This, in turn, reinforces public trust. As
well, gathering a more diverse range of views on the Bank’s activities,
decisions and frameworksand on alternativesultimately leads to better
policy outcomes.
Through these consultations, which took place in 2019 and 2020, the Bank
aimed to:
gain a better understanding of the concerns Canadians have about the
economy and economic policy
learn how the existing framework affects different groups of Canadians
and how the alternative approaches might affect those groups
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 5
assess how well people understand the different monetary policy
frameworks and their trade-offs, since these frameworks are more
effective if Canadians understand them well
gauge people’s awareness, understanding of and support for
unconventional policy tools such as forward guidance and quantitative
easing
The consultations and subsequent public opinion research demonstrated that
Canadians are broadly confident in the Bank’s ability to keep inflation low and
stable, and that public trust in the Bank and the financial system would
remain steady through the COVID-19 pandemic. Continued engagement and
clear communications with Canadians will be required as the Bank navigates a
period of above-target inflation as a result of the unique characteristics of the
economic reopening and recovery from the pandemic.
Many Canadians were open to some change in the Bank’s approach but
generally supported the continued use of inflation targeting. Most viewed the
current inflation-targeting framework as balanced, flexible and the most easily
understood approach. Of the alternatives, a dual mandate received some
interestreflecting a desire by many Canadians for the Bank to consider how
it could support the labour marketbut many questioned whether an
employment target would be achievable. Canadians also indicated an interest
in average inflation targeting, which suggests a desire for more flexibility in
how the Bank achieves the 2 percent target. The other frameworksprice-
level targeting and NGDP targetingwere seen as less achievable or harder
to understand.
The majority of participants emphasized the importance of the Bank being
flexible in how it achieves the inflation target. Specifically, Canadians were
most comfortable with an approach that targets a range for inflation and
adjusts interest rates slowly to achieve the target. Many were open to
accepting longer periods of above- or below-target inflation to support the
economy and jobs.
Outlining the road to renewal
This background document describes the research and analysis that
supported the new agreement on Canada’s monetary policy framework.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 6
Chapter 2 discusses Canada’s experience with inflation targeting. Chapter 3
explores the key challenges in conducting monetary policy given the shifts in
the economic landscape. Chapter 4 provides a detailed discussion of the
Bank’s comparison of alternative policy frameworks. Chapter 5 examines the
full range of monetary policy tools available in the Bank’s tool kit. Finally,
Chapter 6 outlines how the Bank will conduct monetary policy under the
renewed agreement.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 7
Chapter 2: Canada’s experience
with inflation targeting
Over the past 100 years, Canada has used several monetary frameworks.
These have included the gold standard, the Bretton Woods system of pegged
exchange rates, monetary targets and, since the early 1990s, inflation
targeting.
Canada first announced an inflation target in February 1991. After the target’s
introduction, inflation, as measured by the consumer price index (CPI), came
down quickly, and since the late 1990s it has generally been low, stable and
predictable (Chart 1). This stands in sharp contrast to the high inflation of the
1970s and early 1980s.
Inflation spent periods below the 2 percent target during the 200809 global
financial crisis and the 201415 collapse in commodity prices and, in 202021,
during the COVID-19 pandemic. As a result, average inflation following the
global financial crisis up until the pandemic was below 2 percent.
The COVID-19 shock presented unique challenges for monetary policy. The
widespread closure of many sectors of the economy was met with aggressive
fiscal and monetary policy stimulus. This stimulus supported a faster, albeit
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
25
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015
%
Inflation-control range CPI inflation Inflation target
Chart 1:
Introducing inflation targets brought inflation down
12
-month rate of increase, monthly data
Last observation: October 2021
Sources: Statistics Canada and Bank of Canada calculations
Inflation
targeting
Monetary target and
other frameworks
Gold standard
framework
Bretton Woods
system
Bank begins
operations
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 8
uneven, recovery. The strong global recovery, particularly in the demand
for goods, exacerbated supply constraints and higher energy prices. This
led to an average inflation rate of goods in the first 11 months of 2021 of
4.4 percent, well above that of services at 2.1 percent. This contrasts
sharply with recent trends: over the 20 years before the pandemic, goods
inflation averaged only 1.4 percent while inflation for services was 2.4
percent. This rapid rise in inflation for goods was the key driver in above-
target inflation during 2021.
2
Notwithstanding periodic macroeconomic shocks such as the one Canadians
are experiencing as a result of the COVID-19 pandemic, Canada’s flexible
inflation-targeting framework has kept inflation low, stable and predictable
for three decades. It has been robust to a variety of economic circumstances
and has enhanced welfare by fostering a more certain environment where
planning for the future is easier.
Three key factors have contributed to the framework’s success (Carter,
Mendes and Schembri 2018):
The inflation target is straightforward to explain and understand. This has
improved accountability and allowed consistent application of the
framework over time.
The framework is based on an agreement between the Bank of Canada and
the Government of Canada. The joint agreement grants the Bank operational
independence to achieve the inflation target, while emphasizing that inflation
control ultimately remains a shared commitment of both parties. The
agreement also gives the target democratic legitimacy, further enhancing the
target’s credibility and helping to anchor inflation expectations.
The regular, formal and transparent review and renewal process leads to
continual improvement of the framework and its implementation. This
process allows the Bank to incorporate lessons learned from historical
experience and research.
Each renewal cycle has involved analysis of a range of issues. For instance,
during the 2016 cycle, the Bank focused its review and research on the
following three questions:
Should the 2 percent inflation target be increased?
2
Gravelle (2021b) offers a discussion on the role of energy prices, shifts in demand across goods and supply
constraints on consumer prices over 2021.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 9
To what extent should the conduct of monetary policy consider financial
stability?
How should core inflation be measured and used as an operational guide
for the conduct of monetary policy? (Box 1 presents an updated
assessment of the core measures.)
Box 1:
An updated assessment of the core measures
The inflation target in Canada is expressed in terms of consumer price index (CPI)
inflation. Monetary policy achieves the inflation target by influencing domestic
demand for goods and services, which, in turn, affects underlying inflationary
pressures. Many other factors can also influence CPI inflationfor example, changes
in the prices of commodities, which are set in global markets. Because the price
movements are likely to be short-lived and the effects of monetary policy on inflation
are delayed, the Bank of Canada focuses on the underlying rate when making policy
decisions. It also uses forecasts for CPI inflation that go beyond the horizon of the
temporary factors.
For the 2016 renewal of the
inflation-control agreement,
the Bank replaced CPIX
inflation as its preferred
measure of core inflation.
3
It
adopted three other measures
that performed well across a
range of evaluation criteria
CPI-common, CPI-trim and
CPI-median (Chart 1-A).
4
Using these three indicators of
inflation over the past five
years has helped the Bank
manage the risks associated
with relying on any single
indicator.
3 CPIX inflation excluded eight of the most volatile components of the CPI (fruit, vegetables, gasoline, fuel oil,
natural gas, mortgage interest, intercity transportation and tobacco products) and adjusted the remainder for the
effect of changes in indirect taxes.
4 CPI-common uses a statistical procedure to track common price changes across categories in the CPI basket. CPI-
trim excludes upside and downside outliers. CPI-median is the median inflation rate across CPI components. For
details, see Bank of Canada (2016) and Khan, Morel and Sabourin (2015).
0
1
2
3
4
5
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
%
CPI-common CPI-trim CPI-median
Chart 1-A: Measures of core inflation have
provided a useful guide for monetary policy
Year-over-year percentage change, monthly data
Last observation: October 2021
Sources: Statistics Canada and Bank
of Canada calculations
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 10
From 2017 through 2019, the dynamics of all three measures were consistent with an
economy where slack had largely been absorbedall were within a narrow range
and close to 2 percent. The use of these measures as a guide for monetary policy was
tested more recently because of the uneven economic impacts of the pandemic. The
three core inflation measures provided useful insights into underlying inflation given
the unique shifts in demand and supply and the resulting price movements caused
by the pandemic. For example, CPI-common initially fell, reflecting the large amount
of excess capacity in the economy. However, CPI-median and CPI-trim filtered out
most of the weakness in inflation in some hard-to-distance service sectors. As supply
disruptions became prevalent in 2021, CPI-trim and CPI-median increased, reflecting
the inflationary pressures from components experiencing supply constraints.
Consequently, the range between the three measures widened furtherhighlighting
the value of looking at more than one measure of underlying inflation.
5
An updated evaluation of the statistical properties of the core measures confirms
that no single measure dominateseach has strengths and limitations (Table 1-A).
6
Still, the three measures are more useful than others because they effectively capture
persistent movements in inflation and they tend to move with the macroeconomic
variables that monetary policy affects. The current measures also remain less biased
and less volatile than other measures.
While the core measures have helped guide monetary policy, core inflation is just
one of many inputs in the process. It is important to consider the three measures
together with a detailed analysis of the determinants of inflation and broader
measures of capacity pressures. These measures include, but are not limited to,
labour market indicators, wages and other input costs such as commodity prices,
estimates of the output gap, and business and consumer survey results.
Table 1-A: Summary of an evaluation of different core inflation measures
CPI-median
CPI-trim
Unbiased
Persistent
Volatile
Moves with output gap
Looks through sector-specific shocks
Has an easily understood methodology
Top performance
Favourable performance
Neutral performance
Unfavourable performance
5 See Bank of Canada (2021a) for a discussion of the movements in core inflation measures during the pandemic.
6 For details, see Lao and Steyn (2019).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 11
The current review of the inflation-control target builds on the work done in
previous renewal cycles.
Inflation targeting has not only consistently delivered low and stable inflation
but also enhanced the resilience of the economy to external shocks, thereby
reducing volatility and improving overall economic performance.
7
For
example, real economic growth has been much steadier than it was before
the adoption of inflation targeting (as shown by a declining standard
deviation in Table 1). Nominal interest rates have also been lower and more
stable. This is mainly because inflation expectations have declined, but also
because the premiums to compensate investors for inflation risk have, on
average, been smaller.
Overall, the stability in inflation over the past 30 years has increased the
credibility of monetary policy and led to well-anchored inflation expectations.
7 The inflation-targeting regime has contributed to Canada’s improved economic performance for the past 30 years.
It has allowed Canadian businesses and households to read price signals more clearly, to respond to relative price
shocks more promptly and generally to allocate resources more efficiently. Canada’s flexible exchange rate has
complemented the monetary policy framework, facilitating economic adjustment to various internal and external
shocks. Many other factors have also helped improve Canada’s economic performance; these include the
entrenchment of sound fiscal policy, rigorous prudential regulation and supervision, and structural reforms.
Table 1: Canada’s economic performance before and after inflation targeting
Average (percent)
Standard deviation
October 2016 to
October 2021
October 2016 to
October 2021
Jan 1975
to Jan 1991
Feb 1991
to Sept 2016
Oct 2016 to
Dec 2019
Oct 2016 to
Oct 2021
Jan 1975
to Jan 1991
Feb 1991
to Sept 2016
Oct 2016 to
Dec 2019
Oct 2016 to
Oct 2021
CPI: 12-month increase
7.1
1.9
1.9
1.9
2.9
1.1
0.4
1.0
Real GDP growth*
2.8
2.4
2.5
2.2
3.8
2.6
1.3
13.2
Unemployment rate
8.9
8.0
6.1
7.0
1.7
1.5
0.4
1.9
3-month interest rate
10.8
3.5
1.6
1.2
3.0
2.2
0.4
0.7
10-year interest rate§
10.7
4.9
1.9
1.5
2.0
2.2
0.4
0.6
Months in inflation-
control range (percent)
0.0 72.7 100.0 72.1
* This is the annualized quarter-over-quarter growth rate for quarters within the time period. The table incorporates real GDP data
through the third quarter of 2021.
Unemployment data start in January 1976 with the introduction of a new labour force survey.
The 3-month interest rate refers to the 3-month bankers’ acceptance rate.
§
Due to data availability before June 1982, the 10-year interest rate refers to the yield of government bonds with maturations
longer than 10 years; after June 1982, it is based on the 10-year government bond yield from Statistics Canada.
Sources: Statistics Canada, Investment Industry Regulatory Organization of Canada and Bank of Canada calculations
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 12
Public perceptions of current inflation, however, are often higher than
measured inflation (Box 2). Nevertheless, the clarity and simplicity of the
inflation target enhanced the credibility and the general effectiveness of
monetary policy. Furthermore, the target made it easier for the public to hold
the Bank accountable for its performance. Through the years, the Bank has
sought to become more transparent in explaining its conduct of monetary
policy (see Box 10 in Chapter 6).
Box 2:
Differences between perceived and actual inflation
Survey data in several countries, including Canada, point to a gap between measured
and perceived inflation. This could raise concerns that the consumer price index (CPI)
does not accurately reflect inflation as experienced by many Canadians. Large
differences between perceived and actual inflation could eventually undermine the
legitimacy of the inflation-control framework.
The Bank of Canada held
consultations with Canadians
and studied possible
explanations for the
perception-measurement gap.
Responses to the Bank’s
Canadian Survey of Consumer
Expectations (CSCE) reveal the
gap between measures and
perceived inflation in Canada
(Gosselin and Khan 2015).
Households, on average, tend
to believe inflation is higher
than actual CPI inflation as
measured by Statistics Canada
(Chart 2-A). Still, current
perceptions of inflation have
been anchored firmly near the target. Consumer expectations of future inflation tend
to be above the target and vary more than perceptions of current inflation.
8
8 There is also evidence of some backward-looking expectations, as those who expect high inflation in the future
tend to perceive high inflation today.
-1
0
1
2
3
4
5
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
%
Bank of Canada inflation-control target
Official CPI
Current perceptions of inflation
One-year-ahead inflation expectations
Chart 2-A: Households' perceptions of inflation tend
to be higher than official measures
Year-over-year percentage change, quarterly data
Last observation: 2021Q3
Sources: Statistics Canada, Bank of Canada and
Bank of Canada calculations
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 13
Several factors can drive the perception-measurement gap (the difference between
the blue and green lines in Chart 2-A).
First, the CPI basket does not represent the spending habits of all individual
households. While the CPI measures the change in prices of goods and services
purchased by the average household, each household purchases different
proportions of the items in the CPI basket and experiences inflation somewhat
differently. In the Bank’s public consultations, participants said that in their view the
CPI does not effectively capture the rising costs of certain goods and servicesfor
example, the high cost of food in remote communities, education costs or the
growth in housing prices across the country. To assess the importance of these
differences, the Bank and Statistics Canada analyzed how the weights in the CPI
basket could be adjusted to better represent the spending patterns of different
demographic groups.
9
Results show that, on average, inflation rates based on
spending baskets for different cohorts are relatively similar to official CPI inflation.
A second factor driving the perception-measurement gap relates to the concept of
quality adjustment. Essentially, adjustments are made in the CPI to capture changes in
the quality of products as new models or varieties are introduced. But consumers often
do not recognize how much a product is improving over time and may focus on its
rising price rather than its higher value. This phenomenon is particularly important for
products with high rates of technological advancement. Without quality adjustments,
CPI inflation would be only about 0.2 percentage points higher on average, which
would explain just a small portion of the perception-measurement gap.
A third factor driving differences between perceived and actual inflation relates to
housing. Participants in public consultations highlighted the growth in house prices
as key to why they feel inflation is higher than 2 percent. Households usually
consider housing costs to be the acquisition cost. However, in the CPI, housing is
closer to a cost-of-living concept, measured as the imputed cost of services provided
by housing.
10
In recent years, the growth in house prices has tended to be much
greater than the increase in housing costs as measured by the CPI. This difference
can explain about 0.3 percentage points of the gap between actual and perceived
inflation.
Overall, the measurement issues reviewed seem to explain less than half of the
perception-measurement gap. Other behavioural factors might also be at play. For
instance, the loss of purchasing power as a result of significant price increases has
been found to have an outsized psychological impact. To test this, an alternative CPI
9 See Keshishbanoosy et al. (forthcoming).
10 The cost of housing includes all required expenses linked to living in and owning a house, including mortgage
interest costs, home-insurance premiums, maintenance and repairs, and replacement costs. See Sabourin and
Duguay (2015).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 14
inflation was calculated by trimming 20 percent of price declines and 10 percent of
price increases. Households’ expectations were found to be close to this alternative
measure of inflation, suggesting that consumers give more weight to price increases
and that excluding large declines could explain a significant part (0.7 percentage
points) of the gap between actual and perceived inflation.
11
An important explanation of Canadians’ elevated views of inflation could be
information gaps. When information about prices is not readily available or is too
costly to acquire, people rely on their own experiences to form expectations. Central
banks can help fill the information gaps by making information more readily
available and supporting economic literacy. Bank analysis shows that individuals
update their views on inflation when they receive new information, particularly
information about the Bank’s inflation target and about inflation forecasts.
12
Knowledge is also key: the inflation expectations of people with higher financial and
economic literacy are more in line with measured inflation. For instance, in the CSCE
results, the perception-measurement gap is largest for respondents with low levels of
education and income. In this context, new communication strategies to reach a
broader audience and increase financial and economic literacy are worth exploring.
The Bank’s The Economy, Plain and Simple series and the Bank of Canada Museum’s
education programs are steps in that direction.
Large external shocks over the years (such as the global financial crisis and the
COVID-19 pandemic) have led the Bank to use different tools within its
inflation-targeting framework. These have included, for example, forward
guidance and quantitative easing. However, inflation targeting as a framework
has endured, both in Canada and in many countries (Rose 2020). Although
economies faced different experiences during these shocks, no inflation-
targeting central bank moved away from having a clear inflation objective.
11 Perceptions of inflation also appear to be partly determined by a consumer’s own view of the costs of a small set
of products and services, which constantly increase; these include food prices, the cost of renting and house prices
(see Keshishbanoosy et al., forthcoming). However, while studies in other countries have found that recent
shopping experiences and frequent purchases such as gasoline and food may affect households’ overall inflation
expectations, Keshishbanoosy et al. calculate Canadian CPI inflation for frequent purchases and find little
difference over the past five years between the inflation rates of frequent purchases and that of the all-items CPI.
12 For details, see Kostyshyna and Petersen (forthcoming).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 15
Low inflation and maximum sustainable
employment
In essence, inflation targeting is about achieving low inflation together with
maximum employment because, to sustainably achieve either, the economy
needs both. Without maximum sustainable employment, the shortfall in jobs
and incomes will pull inflation below target. And without inflation near its
target and well-anchored inflation expectations, the economy would be less
resilient to various shocks, leading to large fluctuations in employment.
Since maximum employment is not directly observable, and in practice it is
hard to gauge when reached, a range of indicators should be examined to
assess the health of the labour market.
The most common measure of the state of the labour market is the
unemployment rate, which is defined as the percentage of the labour force
that does not have a job and is actively looking for work.
13
Before the
COVID-19 pandemic, the unemployment rate was close to a historic low due
to strong gains in full-time jobs in the service sector (Chart 2, panel a).
13 The labour force is the total number of employed and unemployed in the economy.
Chart 2: Before the pandemic, the unemployment rate was close to a historic
low and the employment rate was rising
Monthly data
Last observation: October 2021
Source: Statistics Canada
4
8
12
16
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
%
a. Unemployment rate
50
55
60
65
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
%
b. Employment rate
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 16
A broader measure of labour market health is the employment rate, which is
the number of employed people as a share of the working-age population.
The maximum sustainable employment rate is determined largely by
structural factors beyond the control of monetary policy. For example, the
employment rate has risen over time (Chart 2, panel b). This is mostly due to
increases in the employment rate for women until the early 2000s. That said,
the inflation-targeting framework has contributed to reducing employment
fluctuations by stabilizing overall demand.
More recently, the pandemic had a large and uneven impact on the labour
market. The effects were more severe for certain sectors and their workers.
Hard-to-distance service industrieswhere physical distancing is either
difficult or impossiblesuffered the most. Meanwhile, industries where
physical distancing or remote work is possiblesuch as professional services,
finance and public administrationwere better able to adapt. These
differences across sectors led to unequal consequences. Low-wage workers,
women and young people were most affected.
Using flexibility
The Bank strives to make forward-looking policy decisions based on several
important considerations, drawing from a wide range of information. To
achieve this, the Bank has introduced a degree of flexibility into the practice
of monetary policy with an inflation target. At times this has led to the use of
different horizons to bring inflation back to target.
A key feature of the current policy framework is a risk management approach
that allows policy-makers to weigh multiple factors and risks during policy
deliberations. These include the risk of having the policy rate constrained by
the effective lower bound (ELB), other forecast risks, employment
considerations and financial stability concerns (Poloz 2020).
14
The Bank uses
a variety of models, data analysis, survey evidence and judgment to inform its
understanding of these factors and risks and how they might interact and
affect its ability to control inflation. The flexibility in the inflation-targeting
14 Kozicki and Vardy (2017) describe the uncertainties that central banks face. For instance, uncertainty is inherent
in measuring economic data and in unobserved metrics. Uncertainty is also linked to the models that are used to
inform policy decisions. And unforeseen developments are always possible.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 17
framework has allowed for adjustments in the expected time horizon for
bringing inflation back to target.
15
Other complementary policies could also help manage the trade-offs faced by
inflation-targeting central banks (Box 3). For example, automatic fiscal
stabilizers that increase spending during economic downturns can also help
monetary policy achieve the inflation objective and stabilize the economy
(MacKay and Reis 2016; Meh and Poloz 2018).
Box 3:
How monetary and fiscal policy can work together
Recent years have seen a revival of research into monetary and fiscal policies and
how they can reduce fluctuations in the business cycle and increase resilience to
external shocks. The 200809 global financial crisis showed that monetary policy
alone may be not be enough to lessen the negative effects of large shocks, especially
certain types. One implication is that the benefits of using both monetary and fiscal
policies to lean against big shocks may be greater than previously thought.
16
Monetary policy can generally react quickly to unanticipated changes in economic
conditions by changing the short-term interest rate, although its full impact on the
economy can take time. Changes to the short-term interest rate affect all firms and
households regardless of their exposure to a shock. Fiscal policy, in contrast, can
more easily target specific groups or sectors through transfer programs that are
quick to implement, which is helpful when shocks affect firms or individuals
differently. This has led some to argue in favour of a complementary approach,
where both monetary and fiscal policies are used to moderate the effects of shocks.
Fiscal policy can contribute to macroeconomic stability through three main policy
tools:
Automatic fiscal stabilizers, such as employment insurance or progressive
personal income taxes, can help stabilize business-cycle fluctuations. They do this
by reducing swings in individuals’ disposable income and redistributing resources
from individuals with higher income to those with lower income. However, the
impact of some automatic stabilizers may be less because they can distort labour
15 See Bank of Canada,Bank of Canada Releases Background Information on Renewal of the Inflation-Control
Target,” press release (November 9, 2011).
16 Dong et al. (2021) review the recent literature on the complementarities between fiscal policy and monetary
policy for stabilizing economic activity.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 18
market behaviour.
17
Because many automatic stabilizers have multiple policy
objectives, how best to design them is an open question.
Changes to public spending and tax instruments can be designed to offset
business-cycle fluctuations by supporting aggregate demand. Some discretiona
ry
f
iscal expenditures have short-term multipliers that are close to or above one
,
w
hich means that each additional dollar of expenditure translates into close to an
additional dollar of output. When interest rates are near the ELB, fiscal stimulus
ha
s a larger impact. While discretionary spending can focus on the specific policy
priorities that are most relevant at the time, they may require legislation an
d
some ca
n take time to implement.
Government credit programs extend credit to certain borrowers and
market segments and can implicitly or explicitly guarantee obligations of
government-sponsored enterprises. These credit policies can mitigate economi
c
downturns that are exacerbated by severe financial market distress.
The policy responses to the economic effects of the COVID-19 pandemic illustrate
how both fiscal and monetary authorities can respond rapidly to large shocks. The
responses to COVID-19 included unprecedented fiscal actions in some countries,
with large-scale programs introduced quickly to offset the sudden loss of income
that some households and firms experienced. While some fiscal policies were
targeted at the most affected households and firms, others were broader-based and
relied on existing transfer and tax systemsin some cases because new programs
take time to implement. Recent research examines the economic impact of various
elements of the fiscal response to the pandemic. For example, MacGee, Pugh and
See (2021) examine how the Canada Emergency Response Benefit (CERB) affected
household savings and debt, and Petit and Tedds (2020) highlight differences in how
Canadian provincial and territorial governments treated CERB payments in assessing
eligibility for income assistance programs.
18
During the pandemic, flexibility was exercised through an aggressive
monetary policy response. The Bank quickly reduced the policy rate to its ELB,
provided forward guidance and used additional tools such as quantitative
17 A variation suggested in the academic literature is a pre-committed fiscal spending formula that would be
triggered by certain macroeconomic conditions. Such a state-contingent, non-discretionary fiscal policy would
have the advantage of being timely and easy to communicate. But identifying appropriate and robust triggers and
sorting out how to develop credibility around the commitments could be challenging.
18 A growing literature examines programs introduced in other countries. For example, Autor et al. (2020) and
Chetty et al. (2020) examine the Paycheck Protection Program (part of the US Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and
Economic Security Act), while Romer (2021) asks whether aspects of the US fiscal response, such as one-time
stimulus payments, were well targeted.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 19
easing to support financial market functioning and reinforce the forward
guidance. The forward guidance demonstrated that even without room to cut
the policy rate further, the Bank can still provide monetary stimulus by making
a commitment to hold the policy rate at its ELB for longer than the degree of
excess capacity might suggest. Given the lags involved in the transmission of
monetary policy, the Bank’s response resulted in a projection for inflation that
temporarily exceeded 2 percent. Nevertheless, the public could be confident
that the Bank would remain focused on the inflation-control mandate even
while pursuing aggressive monetary policy to support a stronger, broader-
based recovery (see Box 8 in Chapter 5).
To maintain its credibility and enhance the public’s trust throughout the
pandemic, the Bank also committed to being transparent about the
parameters of its asset purchase programs and to reporting regularly on the
evolution of the its balance sheet. The Bank’s credibility and independence
were evident in market perceptions following Bank actions. For instance,
market expectations for policy rates generally tracked the Bank’s forward
guidance.
19
In addition, inflation expectations stabilized—allowing reductions
in the policy rate to be more fully passed through to real borrowing costs.
20
The results of the Bank’s consultations show that Canadians’ trust in the Bank
held firm or increased slightly during the pandemic and that people are highly
confident the Bank can continue to achieve its inflation target (Bank of
Canada 2021b).
19 The Bank’s commitment in July 2020 to leave the policy rate at the ELB was contingent on achieving the inflation
target on a sustainable basis. Following that announcement, market expectations for the policy rate flattened. In
October, the Bank reinforced its commitment and specified that it did not expect to sustainably meet the inflation
objective until some time in 2023. This updated forecast was credible because market pricing after the October
announcement had the policy rate at the ELB until at least 2023. As the outlook brightened in late 2020, market
pricing beyond 202223 moved slightly higher. But short-term yields remained anchored by the forward guidance.
In October 2021, the Bank’s projection was updated as the recovery progressed. The commitment to hold the
policy rate at the ELB until economic slack is absorbed so that the 2 percent inflation target is sustainably achieved
was then revised to sometime in the middle quarters of 2022.
20 Professional forecasters’ long-term inflation expectations remain firmly anchored at 2 percent, while consumer
expectations in the Canadian Survey of Consumer Expectations and business expectations in the Business Outlook
Survey have bounced back relative to their 2020 levels. Market-based measures of expectations fell at the start of
the crisis, recovered as the Bank rolled out its quantitative easing program, and ticked up with the Bank’s decision
in July 2020 to commit to holding the policy rate steady until the inflation objective is sustainably achieved.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 20
Chapter 3: Key challenges for the
conduct of monetary policy
Over the past decade or so, several economic trends have accelerated,
affecting the Canadian economy. The 200809 global financial crisis and the
COVID-19 pandemic have had significant impacts on the global economy and
financial system. And forces such as demographic shifts, globalization, new
digital technologies and climate change are affecting the economic
landscape.
These economic and social trends raise two key challenges for the conduct of
monetary policy:
The persistence of low interest rates since the global financial crisis has led
to a growing consensus that low neutral rates are likely to continue for
some time, constraining central banks ability to provide stimulus through
reductions in their policy rate.
Major forces have increased uncertainty and made it harder to pin down
the maximum level of employment that the economy can sustain before
inflationary pressures build.
In addition, when conducting monetary policy, central banks need to consider
the historically high levels of debt held by households and businesses.
Despite significant advances in prudential financial regulations, particularly
with respect to housing finance, a prolonged period of low interest rates
could contribute to a buildup of financial vulnerabilities. Thus, while a number
of prudential, macroprudential and housing policy instruments are better
suited than monetary policy to address financial vulnerabilities, the possibility
that monetary policy could exacerbate these vulnerabilities remains an
important consideration.
A world of low neutral interest rates
The low interest rates observed in advanced economies since the global
financial crisis partly reflect low neutral rates, which many agree are likely to
persist in the coming years (e.g., Del Negro et al. 2019). This persistence
means central banks will have less room to lower their policy rates before
hitting the effective lower bound (ELB). As a result, ELB episodes are more
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 21
likely to occur in the future than they were during the first two decades of
inflation targeting. Given the tendency for inflation to be below target during
ELB episodes, more frequent ELB episodes may make it difficult for the Bank
of Canada to achieve its inflation target of 2 percent.
To assess the likelihood of an ELB episode, we use the concept of the neutral
rate of interest. The neutral rate is defined as the policy rate that coincides
with output at potential and inflation equal to target after the effects of
cyclical shocks have dissipated. Although estimates vary across countries and
time periods, most agree that the neutral rate of interest has declined in
advanced economies since at least the early 2000s and is likely to remain near
its historical lows over the coming years.
21
In Canada, both the actual policy rate and the estimated neutral rate have
declined since the early 2000s (Chart 3). In the mid-2000s, the Bank assumed
a nominal neutral rate of roughly 5 percent. Since the global financial crisis,
estimates have shifted downward, and the 2021 Canadian nominal neutral
rate estimate is in the range of 1.75 to 2.75 percent, with a midpoint of
2.25 percent (Brouillette et al. 2021).
21 See, for example, Laubach and Williams (2003), Del Negro et al. (2019) and Feunou and Fontaine (forthcoming).
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
1991 1996 2001 2006 2011 2016 2021
Effective lower bound (+25 basis points) Policy rate Estimated neutral rate
Note: The grey range is the estimated range of the neutral rate, and the black line is the mid point of the range.
Source: Bank of Canada
%
Last observation: October 2021
Chart 3: The Bank of Canada policy rate and the estimated neutral rate
have declined
Monthly
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 22
This decline in the neutral rate makes it more likely that monetary policy will
reach its ELB in future economic downturns. With a lower neutral rate, central
banks have less room to reduce the policy rate in response to negative shocks
before reaching the ELB. Staff estimate that the likelihood that adverse
economic shocks will result in the policy rate hitting its stated ELB of
0.25 percent has increased from 6 percent in 2016 to about 17 percent in
2021 (Chart 4, panel a).
22
The lower neutral rate has also extended the
projected average duration of ELB episodes from 2.3 quarters in 2016 to
about 7 quarters in 2021 (Chart 4, panel b).
The recent experience with the COVID-19 pandemic illustrates the
implications of ELB episodes for inflation (see Chapter 2). Even with a rapid
decrease of the policy rate to the ELB in response to weak aggregate demand,
inflation fell well below the 2 percent target. This is consistent with analysis
that ELB episodes often see inflation below target.
The risk of frequent and prolonged ELB episodes where inflation is
persistently below target has raised concerns that inflation, over the medium
term, may average below 2 percent. If inflation were to average below target
for a prolonged period, households and firms could adjust their inflation
expectations downward. This would cause the ELB to become even more of a
22 Staff used the Bank’s main dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model, the Terms-of-Trade Economic Model
(ToTEM) III, for this analysis. See Corrigan et al. (2021) for details on ToTEM III.
data
Chart 4: The probability of being constrained by the effective lower bound on
the policy interest rate has increased
Note: In both panels, the 2021 real neutral rate is 0.25 percent, the 2016 real neutral rate is 1.25 percent and the real neutral rate before
the global financial crisis is 3 percent. Rates are calculated using the Bank of Canada’s Terms
-of-Trade Economic Model (ToTEM) III.
Source: Bank of Canada
0
2
4
6
8
2021 real neutral
rate
2016 real neutral
rate
Real neutral rate
before global
financial crisis
Quarters
b. Average duration of effective lower bound episodes
0
5
10
15
20
2021 real neutral
rate
2016 real neutral
rate
Real neutral rate
before global
financial crisis
%
a. Relative frequency of a binding effective
lower bound
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 23
constraint because it would be more difficult to reduce the real policy rate. As
a result, central banks need to adjust how they conduct monetary policy.
Changes could include using a larger suite of monetary policy tools and
approaches more often. This would better mitigate the impacts of ELB
episodes on employment and output and help avoid inflation remaining
below 2 percent for extended periods of time (see Chapter 5).
Increased uncertainty about the level of maximum
sustainable employment
Major forces, including demographic changes, technological advancements,
globalization and shifts in the nature of work, have had profound effects on
the Canadian labour market. These evolving forces have increased uncertainty
around assessments of the level of maximum sustainable employmentthe
highest level of employment that the economy can sustain before inflationary
pressures build. Added to this uncertainty is increasing evidence that the
relationship between economic slack and inflation is relatively weak as long as
inflation expectations remain firmly anchored.
23
As a result, inflation near
2 percentby itselfis no longer a sufficient signal that the economy has
reached maximum sustainable employment.
The increased uncertainty about the level of maximum sustainable
employment poses a challenge to the conduct of monetary policy. When
deciding on monetary policy actions, the Bank looks ahead and adjusts the
degree of monetary stimulus to affect the level of total demand and help
close the output gap. Because inflation expectations are well anchored at
2 percent, inflation should return sustainably to target when slack is absorbed
and the economy is restored to maximum sustainable employment and its
productive capacity. However, with increased uncertainty regarding the level
of maximum sustainable employment, the risk of misjudging the appropriate
stance for monetary policy has increased.
Identifying the level of maximum sustainable employment has never been
easy. Indeed, many researchers have documented the wide confidence
intervals associated with estimates of the output gap or of the non-
23 Economic slack refers to resources in the economy that are not being fully utilized. These resources include
people who would like to work but are unable to find a job as well as machinery and equipment that are not being
used.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 24
accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU)—a commonly used
measure of maximum sustainable employment. It should not be surprising
that identifying maximum sustainable employment is challenging because the
labour market itself is not one single market. It is, in fact, the sum of many
markets, differentiated by a variety of characteristics, including skill, industry
and location. Consequently, it is difficult to know whether everyone who
wants to be working is doing so, in a job that matches their skill set.
Ongoing structural changes in labour markets over the past few decades have
caused the level of maximum sustainable employment to change, making this
challenge even greater (Box 4). For example, an aging population and higher
levels of immigration have had an impact on the mix of workers’ skills. At the
same time, globalization and technological changeespecially
digitalizationhave affected labour demand. These still-evolving forces have
shifted the demand for and supply of different skill sets, and their net effect
on maximum sustainable employment is unclear.
Box 4:
Evolving uncertainties about the estimation of the
output gap and maximum sustainable employment
Economic research has documented the substantial uncertainties around the
measurement of unobservable variables, such as the output gap and maximum
sustainable employment.
24
These variables feature prominently in the
macroeconomic models that central banks use to predict when inflationary pressures
will emerge.
Structural changes in labour marketsdriven by ongoing demographic shifts,
globalization and technological change, especially digitalizationhave heightened
these uncertainties. These changes are affecting the demand for and supply of
different skill sets and possibly creating job mismatches. Since the 200809 global
financial crisis, employment rates (defined as the ratio of employed individuals to
24 Champagne, Poulin-Bellisle and Sekkel (2018) and Barnett, Kozicki and Petrinec (2009) show that the Bank of
Canada’s real-time estimates of the output gap are subject to large revisions. Similar results have been found for
other countries. For example, Orphanides and Van Norden (2002) show that real-time econometric estimates of
the output gap in the United States are subject to large revisions. Uncertainties around estimates of the non-
accelerating inflation rate of unemployment in Canada have been documented by Rose (1988) and Setterfield,
Gordon and Osberg (1992). Recent work by Brouillette et al. (2019) also finds that estimates of the trend
unemployment rate in Canada continue to come with large confidence intervals. These uncertainties around
estimates of maximum sustainable employment are also well established for other countries. For example, Staiger,
Stock and Watson (1997) report that it is not uncommon for the 95 percent confidence bands for the US NAIRU to
be roughly 3 percentage points.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 25
working-age population) for both men and women have remained below their pre-
recession levels (see Chapter 2). These lower employment rates are partly due to
long-term declines in the labour force participation rates of individuals aged 15 to
24, which are the result of increased school enrolment. However, these changes have
been accompanied by a rising prevalence of part-time or short-term work, especially
among young Canadians.
25
A related but distinct trend is the increase in “gig”
employment in which the worker is an independent contractor rather than an
employee.
26
While the net effects of these forces on maximum sustainable employment are
unclear, uncertainty about the level of maximum employment appears to be
particularly high after recessions. All of the decline in jobs involving routine work in
Canada occurred during recessions (Blit 2020), reinforcing the notion that firms
restructure their production processes during these times.
27
The share of long-term
unemployed workers rose in Canada during the global financial crisis (Kroft et al.
2019). A longer duration of joblessness not only increases the tendency for
unemployed individuals to leave the labour force but also reduces the likelihood that
non-participants will enter the labour force to search for jobs.
28
This suggests that
the trends in labour force participation and job polarization are intertwined. Areas
more severely hit by the global financial crisis in the United States observed a
persistent decline in their employment rates as workers chose to leave the labour
force (Yagan 2019), suggesting the possibility of labour market hysteresis.
29
The question of how to respond to increased uncertainty about the level of
maximum sustainable employment is further complicated by growing
evidence that the slope of the Phillips curvethe relationship between
inflation and economic slack for a given level of expected future inflationis
flatter than previously thought. This means that inflation is less sensitive to
25 Morissette (2021) finds that since 1976, among youth aged 1530 who are not in school, the proportion working
part-time as opposed to full-time jobs has increased substantially, and most of this increase has been involuntary.
26 More information about the gig economy can be found in Kostyshyna and Luu (2019) and Jeon, Liu and
Ostrovsky (2019). Also, for research on multiple-jobholding patterns, see Kostyshyna and Lalé (2019).
27 A growing line of research classifies jobs as routine or non-routine based on descriptions of the tasks required.
Jaimovich and Siu (2020) suggest that the hollowing out of routine jobs in the United States is concentrated
during recessions.
28 The unemployment rate is an imperfect measure of total slack (excess capacity in the form of potential workers)
in the labour market. For example, during a downturn, previously active job seekers may get discouraged and stop
looking for work, and people intending to enter the labour force may put off doing so. At such times, participation
in the labour market falls, and this can give misleading signals about how much employment really exists.
29 For a recent examination of the similarities between the Canadian and US labour markets, see Albouy et al.
(2019).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 26
changes in economic conditions. The evolving view of the relationship
between inflation and economic slack reflects not only the success of inflation
targeting in anchoring inflation expectations since the 1990s but also recent
research (Box 5).
30
Box 5:
Implications of a flat Phillips curve
The Phillips curve (PC) plays an important role in macroeconomic modelling in
academia and at central banks. Broadly speaking, the PC relates inflation to a
measure of economic slack, such as the output gap or the deviation of
the
unemployment rate from an estimate of its natural rate and expected future
inflation.
31
Although estimates of the PC can depend on model specification and sample period,
evidence is growing that the slope of the PC since the early 1990s has been relatively
flat (Landry and Sekkel, forthcoming).
32
A flatter slope of the PC means that large
fluctuations in the output gap are consistent with relatively stable inflation (Ball and
Mazumder 2011; Del Negro et al. 2020).
The flatness of the slope of the PC has important implications for how informative
inflation is about whether the economy is close to the maximum sustainable level of
employment (or potential output). In practice, inflation is measured imperfectly, and
transitory shocks (e.g., short-term supply disruptions) can temporarily affect the level
of inflation. With a flat PC and shocks to inflation, inflation can often be close to
2 percent even if the economy is below (or above) maximum sustainable
employment
or potential output.
33
30 See Kryvtsov and MacGee (2020) for a review of recent research on inflation dynamics and experience with
below-target inflation.
31 See Cacciatore, Matveev and Sekkel (forthcoming) for a more in-depth discussion.
32 The formulation of the PC has evolved together with macroeconomic thinking (see Gordon 2011). Beaudry and
Doyle (2000) estimate an accelerationist version of the PC for Canada and detect a decrease in the slope around
1990. Kichian (2001) estimates a time-varying parameter PC and finds similar evidence. Recent structural estimates
of the New Keynesian PC by Corrigan et al. (2021) also find a relatively flat PC for Canada. Recent innovative work
by Hazell et al. (2020) uses US regional data to identify the slope of the PC and concludes that the slope has been
flat since the 1980s. Furthermore, they argue that the sharp drop of inflation in the United States during the 1980s
was mostly due to shifting long-term inflation expectations. Similarly, Fitzgerald et al. (2020) use data from
metropolitan statistical areas in the United States from 1976 to 2010 and find a stable relationship between the
unemployment rate and inflation. Ongoing research explores the possibility of a convex PCthat is, the slope of
the PC increases the more the economy grows above potential. To date, the literature has not reached a clear
consensus on the convexity of the PC (Cacciatore, Matveev and Sekkel, forthcoming).
33 The estimated slope can depend on whether one uses a measure of core consumer price index (CPI) inflation or
total CPI. Although measures of core inflation are less volatile than total CPI and provide a better measure of
underlying inflationary pressures, they do not filter out all temporary shocks (see Box 1).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 27
An example that illustrates how a flatter PC could lead to current inflation being less
informative about maximum sustainable employment is shown in Chart 5-A. Building
from a two-equation model where inflation and potential output are both subject to
unobservable shocks, Cacciatore, Matveev and Sekkel (forthcoming) infer the
probability distribution for the output gap, conditional on inflation being at
2 percent.
34
Shaded areas in the chart represent the probability of the level of the
output gap (with 95 percent confidence). The two curves correspond to pre- and
post-1990s estimates of the slope of the PC reported by Hazell et al. (2020). With a
flatter slope (seen in the smaller value of the slope coefficient, κ), the distribution of
the output gap becomes much more dispersed. As a result, with inflation at
2 percent, a flatter slope means that confidence that the output gap is closed is
much lower.
A relatively flat Phillips curve poses a two-sided risk to monetary policy. On
one hand, it suggests that a more patient approach to tightening monetary
policy could have modest impacts on inflation in the near term. On the other
hand, it implies that if monetary policy is slow to respond to a sustained
34 Carter and Mendes (forthcoming) offer an alternative approach that allows the PC to take a nonlinear, convex
shape under which the curve steepens as the output gap becomes more positive. In this context, inflation
outcomes are relatively uninformative about the maximum sustainable level of output at low levels of output but
become more informative at higher levels of output.
Chart 5
-A: A flatter Phillips curve means inflation is less informative about the
output gap
Note: The two distributions of the output gap are derived using alternative values of the slope of the Phillips curve,
κ, taken from
Hazell et al. (2020). The pre
-1990s value is 0.0107 and the post-1990s value is 0.005.
-15 -10 -5 0
Output gap (percent)
κ
0.0107
κ
0.005
5 10 15
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 28
buildup of inflationary pressures, bringing inflation back to its target may be
costly.
With a flatter Phillips curve, observing inflation near 2 percent is less likely to
imply that the economy is operating near maximum sustainable employment
(see Box 5). Given the uncertainty associated with ongoing structural changes
in labour markets, this suggests that it is now more difficult to know when
maximum sustainable employment is attained and the output gap is closed.
This raises the question of whether changes to the practice of monetary
policy could help the Bank better assess the maximum level of sustainable
employment consistent with the 2 percent target for inflation. For example, a
patient approach to applying monetary stimulus could help draw individuals
with limited attachment to the labour force into more productive employment
and help reduce persistent disparities in economic opportunity and income.
However, inflation expectations must remain well anchored for monetary
policy to succeed in keeping inflation on target.
Historically high levels of private debt
The historically high level of debt relative to gross domestic product (GDP)
among households and businesses remains an important consideration for
the conduct of monetary policy. Since 1990, household sector debt relative to
GDP has doubled and now exceeds 100 percent.
35
Although private, non-
financial business debt has grown more slowly since 1990, it also exceeds
100 percent of GDP.
36
With the expectation that interest rates will remain low
as a result of a low neutral rate of interest, the risk of a further buildup of debt
and associated financial vulnerabilities remains a concern (e.g., see the Bank’s
2021 Financial System Review).
Since the 2016 renewal of the monetary policy framework, the Bank has been
mindful of the risks associated with high levels of household or corporate
debt (Bank of Canada 2016). Elevated debt levels may create a difficult trade-
off between stabilizing inflation today and doing so tomorrow in the face of
35 Despite the doubling of household debt relative to GDP, the fraction of household income spent on debt
payments remains slightly below its 1990 level. While the rise in debt has led to higher principal payments, the fall
in nominal interest rates has lowered interest payments by more.
36 For a discussion of some of the challenges involved in measuring private, non-financial business debt, see
Duprey, Grieder and Hogg (2017).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 29
financial vulnerabilities or macroeconomic imbalances (Beaudry 2020a).
37
Monetary policy can mitigate some concerns about elevated financial
vulnerabilities by flexibly adjusting both the horizon for returning inflation to
target and the corresponding interest rate path (Bank of Canada 2011; 2016).
One tool to help quantify these potential trade-offs is the Bank’s recently
developed growth-at-risk framework (Adrian, Boyarchenko and Giannone
2019; Duprey and Ueberfeldt 2020; Boire, Duprey and Ueberfeldt 2021). While
the growth-at-risk framework offers important insight, research continues on
how best to model the intertemporal trade-off generated by elevated debt
levels and incorporate it into monetary policy decision making.
38
Research is continuing into the mix of policies that could best mitigate and
limit the buildup of financial vulnerabilities.
39
Based on the recent Canadian
experience, a variety of prudential, macroprudential and housing policy
instruments exist that are better suited than monetary policy to address these
vulnerabilities (Box 6). Further investments in strengthening Canada’s
macroprudential policy framework could also potentially increase the
effectiveness of these policies (International Monetary Fund 2019). Given the
importance of financial stability for good macroeconomic performance, this
issue will remain important for monetary policy.
40
37 The Bank discussed the possibility that some alternative paths for the policy rate could have similar implications
for inflation but different implications for the level of financial vulnerabilities. This illustrates that in some
situations no trade-off may exist between stabilizing inflation today and stabilizing it tomorrow in the face of
financial vulnerabilities. Monetary policy can also be a blunt and costly tool to target financial vulnerabilities,
especially compared with other tools such as macroprudential policies (Bank of Canada 2016).
38 The growth-at-risk concept provides a quantitative assessment of the trade-offs between different risks. In this
framework, choosing a rate path to minimize the departure of inflation from the target not only minimizes
macroeconomic risks to economic growth but also has consequences for financial stability risks to economic
growth. The framework still involves an element of judgment, as many of the relationships are estimated
imprecisely. Current research focuses on developing a framework that is more explicit about the mechanisms at
playfor example, exploring the formation of expectations, which can play a key role in the development of
financial vulnerabilities because departures from rational expectations can amplify boom-bust dynamics.
39 For a recent example, see Schroth (2021).
40 A related consideration is that high levels of debt may affect the transmission of monetary policy (e.g., Kaplan,
Moll and Violante 2018; Cloyne, Ferreira and Surico 2020). For example, Kartashova and Zhou (2020) examine how
Canadians with mortgages, which account for the majority of household debt, respond to changes in interest rates
when their mortgages come up for renewal. The authors find that changes in interest rates at renewal have an
asymmetric impact on consumer durable spending, deleveraging and defaults, with borrowers deleveraging if
rates rise at renewal. These asymmetric responses point to a risk that consumption could become more sensitive
to changes in interest rates.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 30
Box 6:
Macroprudential and monetary policyCanadian
experience since the global financial crisis
For over a decade, the Bank of Canada has emphasized the evolution of household
financial vulnerabilities in its Financial System Review. Macroprudential policies have
adapted to address the vulnerabilities in Canadian housing and mortgage markets. In
particular, federal authoritiesboth the Department of Finance Canada and the
Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions (OSFI)implemented and
expanded stress tests for insured and uninsured mortgages. These built on earlier
measures introduced between 2008 and 2012 to lower the riskiness of new mortgage
debt.
Following the global financial crisis, federal mortgage insurance qualification criteria
were tightened. Between 2008 and 2012, the maximum amortization of insured
mortgages was lowered from 40 to 25 years, and the loan-to-value (LTV) ratio limit
was reduced from 100 to 95 percent for a purchase and from 95 to 80 percent for
refinancing.
41
Overall, the rule tightening likely contributed to slower credit growth
after 2012 despite continued low interest rates (Chart 6-A).
The Bank’s policy rate remained constant between September 2010 and January
2015. In 2015, a sharp decline in oil prices prompted the Bank to cut its policy rate to
50 basis points. This reduction, along with continued downward pressure on long-
term yields in international markets, pushed five-year fixed-rate mortgages down to
then-record lows of 2.4 percent (Chart 6-A). This period of low mortgage rates also
saw a steady increase in the share of insured mortgage originations (with LTV ratios
above 80 percent) and uninsured mortgage originations (with LTV ratios less than
80 percent) with a loan-to-income (LTI) ratio over 450 percent.
41 For an overview of the Canadian mortgage market and related policy tools, see Ahnert, Bengui and Peterson
(forthcoming) and Kuncl (2016). In Canada, a refinance is defined as a mortgage origination where borrowers
either increase the amount borrowed (i.e., cash out) or extend the remaining amortization. In addition, some
mortgage renewals allow a borrower to switch lenders at the end of a mortgage term and sign a new contract
with a new interest rate and mortgage term. The ability to renew a mortgage is not affected by the rule changes
regarding refinancing.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 31
To counteract this growth of highly indebted households, the Department of Finance
Canada expanded the stress test for insured mortgages in 2016, while OSFI
expanded the stress test for uninsured mortgages in 2018.
42
These tightenings of
policy by federal authorities effectively increased by 200 basis points the rate used to
calculate the maximum debt service ratio to qualify for a mortgage. The result was a
sharp decline in the share of newly originated mortgages with an LTI ratio greater
than 450 percent.
43
Overall, the recent Canadian experience suggests that the macroprudential measures
on mortgages from 2008 to 2012, along with the expansion of stress tests in 2016,
have dampened credit growth resulting from lower policy rates. The stress test on
insured mortgages has worked to limit the growth of highly leveraged borrowers
(with a high LTI ratio and an LTV ratio at 95 percent). However, interest rates still
42 For more details on the expanded stress tests, see Bank of Canada (2018).
43 The OSFI stress test coincided with an increase in interest rates, which makes it difficult to separate the effects of
the stress test from those of higher mortgage rates (see Ahnert, Bengui and Peterson, forthcoming).
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
%
%
Real estate secured lending (left scale) Policy rate (right scale)
Rule tightenings
Insured
mortgages
OSFI uninsured
mortgages
Note: OSFI refers to the Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions.
Source: Bank of Canada
Last observation: September 2021
Expanded stress tests
Chart 6
-A. Tightening macroprudential policy has contributed to slowing
credit growth despite lower policy rates
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 32
appear to have a strong effect on the Canadian housing market and mortgage
originations.
44
The bottom line is that evidence suggests that macroprudential measures have
countered the buildup of financial vulnerabilities in Canada, lowering the likelihood
and severity of a shock affecting the entire financial system. However, household
debt remains elevated, and house prices have continued to increase rapidly. Thus,
the ability of macroprudential policy to prevent excessive risk taking during a period
of low interest rates may be incomplete. For this reason, monetary policy must be
mindful of its potential effects on financial vulnerabilities.
44 A related question is whether the buildup of financial vulnerabilities can contribute to future contractions in the
economy (as highlighted by Adrian, Boyarchenko and Giannone 2019). That is, can financial vulnerabilities create
macroeconomic risk independent of systemic financial risk? And if so, should macroeconomic stability be
considered a macroprudential policy objective in addition to that of managing systemic risk to the financial
system?
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 33
Chapter 4: Lessons from a comparison
of alternative frameworks
As the 2021 renewal approached, important economic challengesincluding
the lower neutral policy rate and uncertainty in the labour marketplayed
key roles in shaping a broad-based review of the Bank of Canada’s monetary
policy framework. The Bank thus conducted a “horse race” that consisted of a
side-by-side review of the main alternatives to inflation targeting.
45
This
review involved model simulations, lab experiments and public consultations.
In addition to the Bank’s existing flexible inflation-targeting (FIT) framework,
the comparison included:
average inflation targeting (AIT)
price-level targeting (PLT)
an employment-inflation dual mandate
nominal gross domestic product (NGDP)level targeting
NGDP-growth targeting
The Bank considered these frameworks because of their potential to address
the challenges discussed in Chapter 3. They are also the alternative
frameworks that have received the most attention in the economics literature
and in the broader discussion of monetary policy. Results from model
simulations, lab experiments and public consultations all factored into the
Bank’s evaluation of the frameworks against a range of qualitative and
quantitative criteria.
The analytical findings of the horse race align broadly with the results of
consultations with experts and the Canadian public. The current FIT
framework, AIT and a dual mandate were favoured over the other regimes,
which represented a larger departure from the status quo. In addition, while
neither AIT nor a dual mandate was judged to be better than FIT, the analysis
found value in some elements of each of these two alternatives.
45 In past renewals, the Bank considered specific modifications or alternatives to the existing framework, such as
changing the level of the inflation target or adopting price-level targeting.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 34
Key differences in the frameworks
The frameworks differ primarily in their degree of history dependence and
whether they include an explicit role for stabilization of a real variable.
Degree of history dependence
A framework is history-dependent if current policy relies on past outcomes,
even if those past outcomes are otherwise no longer relevant to how the
economy is evolving.
46
All else being equal, frameworks that involve a
commitment to make up for past deviations from some target variables
involve more history dependence than others. If individuals and private sector
businesses understand this commitment, it can shape their expectations and
behaviour. This influence on private sector expectations is particularly
beneficial when the policy rate is constrained by the effective lower bound
(ELB). Inflation is usually lower than the target during much of an ELB episode,
so it must subsequently “overshoot,” or be higher than, the target under a
history-dependent framework. This can help create expectations that the
policy rate will stay low for a longer period than would be required to return
inflation to target. Such expectations can stimulate demand even when the
policy rate is constrained by the ELB because they can affect long-term
borrowing rates, the exchange rate and asset prices. These results depend
critically on how the framework can condition the expectations of market
participants, businesses and the broader public.
In the horse race, the degree of history dependence embedded in the target
variables differs.
Flexible inflation targeting: Monetary policy aims to achieve the inflation
target on a forward-looking basis, without reference to past deviations of
inflation from the target. The specification of the target variable does not
depend on history. In other words, bygones are bygones.
Average inflation targeting: Monetary policy seeks to return a finite,
multi-year average of inflation to 2 percent. Since observations eventually
drop out of the averaging window and cease to be relevant, AIT has some
history dependence in the specification of the target variable.
46 See Woodford (2003) for a more detailed discussion of the definition and role of history dependence in
monetary policy.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 35
Price-level targeting: Monetary policy seeks to make up for all past
deviations of inflation from its target to return the price level to a
predetermined target path that is consistent with 2 percent average
inflation. The average is calculated from a fixed date in the past, so the
averaging window grows over time. This approach carries a higher degree
of history dependence than AIT.
Dual mandate: A dual mandate could be implemented by adding an
employment mandate to any of FIT, PLT or AIT, so the degree of history
dependence hinges on the price stability goal. In the Bank’s horse race, the
focus is on adding an employment objective to FIT, so no history
dependence is embedded in the target variables.
NGDP-level targeting: Monetary policy seeks to maintain the level of
NGDP on a predetermined path that is consistent with a targeted average
nominal growth rate. As under PLT, this results in a high degree of history
dependence.
NGDP-growth targeting: Monetary policy aims to stabilize NGDP growth
around a target rate. As under FIT, there is no history dependence in the
specification of the target variable.
In a wide range of macroeconomic models, the appropriate degree of history
dependence generally depends on the extent to which the private sector is
assumed to form its inflation expectations on a rational, forward-looking
basis. If private sector expectations are mostly rational and forward-looking,
then highly history-dependent frameworks such as PLT tend to perform best
due to their influence on inflation expectations. In contrast, if private sector
expectations are largely backward-looking, then history dependence can lead
to volatility in the real economy. Therefore, how these expectations are
modelled plays an important role in the evaluation of the alternative
frameworks.
Stabilization of a real economy variable
The frameworks also differ in terms of whether or not they include an explicit
role for stabilization of a real variable, such as output or employment, in
response to shocks.
Flexible inflation targeting: The Bank’s current FIT framework does not
include an explicit objective to stabilize a real economy variable, but the
real economy’s performance is nonetheless a central consideration. Full
employment and output at potential are necessary conditions for
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 36
achieving the inflation target on a sustained basis. In addition, the FIT
framework’s flexibility allows the Bank to consider implications for the real
economy when determining how quickly to return inflation to target.
Average inflation targeting: Similar to FIT, AIT does not include an explicit
real economy objective, but achieving full employment and output at
potential are necessary for keeping average inflation sustainably on target
over a prescribed period.
Price-level targeting: Similar to FIT, PLT does not include an explicit real
economy objective, but full employment and output at its potential are
necessary for keeping the price level sustainably on its target path.
Dual mandate: With a distinct goal related to employment, a dual
mandate makes the stabilization of employment more explicit than under
FIT.
NGDP-level or -growth targeting: NGDP-level and -growth targets
naturally include an explicit role for output or output growth stabilization
because NGDP is the product of the GDP price deflator and real GDP.
Results of the comparison
The Bank evaluated the frameworks using simulations in several different
economic models. The use of multiple models helps to isolate the key
mechanisms and assess the robustness of the main results. The Bank also
tested the frameworks in laboratory experiments in which participants were
asked to make decisions in the context of artificial economies. Finally, the
Bank’s extensive public consultations provided useful insights into Canadians’
views on the alternative monetary policy frameworks (Box 7).
Box 7:
Public consultations on monetary policy frameworks
In 201920, the Bank of Canada asked Canadians for their views about the current
inflation-targeting framework as well as several alternative frameworks. In an online
survey and focus groups, the Bank asked how well people thought each of the
frameworks could:
achieve low and stable inflation
provide a solid environment for growth and jobs
support financial stability
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 37
The Bank also asked how easy it would be to communicate each of the frameworks
to Canadians. More than 8,500 individuals completed the survey. Perceptions about
the difficulty in understanding each alternative framework were similar across all
demographic profiles, including age, gender, salary and education.
Low, stable inflation is most important to Canadians
Overall, over half of respondents (53 percent) said they would prefer to have stable
and predictable inflation so that they can better plan their lives. Only 27 percent said
steady economic growth was more important, while 20 percent said maximum
sustainable employment was more important.
Participants felt the groups most affected by inflation were people on fixed incomes,
the economically disadvantaged and seniors. Focus group participants frequently
mentioned growing inequality and disparities between havesand have notsas
issues they cared about. Many participants recognized and valued the important role
controlling inflation can play in mitigating inequality.
Views on monetary policy frameworks were diverse
In the consultations, Canadians expressed a variety of views on the different
monetary policy frameworks under review. Average inflation targeting was seen as
the easiest to understand of the alternatives to flexible inflation targeting (FIT), as
well as the easiest framework for the Bank to achieve. Participants said they prefer
that the Bank take longer to get back to the target with smoother adjustments in
interest rates over a longer period rather than moving quickly back to the target with
sharp and rapid interest rate changes.
Most of the survey respondents (80 percent) said a dual mandate was easy or
somewhat easy to understand. Almost 60 percent felt it would be difficult to achieve,
while almost 40 percent thought it would not be better than the current framework.
A dual mandate also elicited the most polarized responses. Many participants
suggested it could lead to the Bank becoming too politicized, and they questioned
how much of an impact monetary policy could ultimately have on employment.
About half of participants indicated they thought nominal gross domestic product
(NGDP)growth targeting would not improve upon the Bank’s current framework.
NGDP-growth targeting was also least likely to be identified as the approach that
would best serve Canadians.
Overall, most people consulted supported the continued use of FIT as the Bank’s
approach to monetary policy. They recognized that a targeted range for inflation
works well for different economic situations and allows for a smoother adjustment in
interest rates over a longer time period. The majority viewed inflation targeting as
the most easily understood approach.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 38
Criteria
The Bank used a range of quantitative and qualitative criteria to evaluate the
alternative frameworks.
Macroeconomic stability: Because the effects of monetary policy are
primarily macroeconomic in nature, much of the evaluation focused on
stability of prices and of the real economy (e.g., output and employment).
Financial stability: A number of prudential, macroprudential and housing
policy instruments are better suited to address financial vulnerabilities, but
the monetary policy framework can also have implications for financial
stability.
Distributional impact: The Bank sought to understand the distributional
implications of alternative frameworks. Structural factors tend to affect
long-term distributional trends, but the choice of monetary policy
framework can influence inequality during short-term fluctuations in the
economy.
Robustness: A monetary policy framework must perform well in many
different circumstances. For this reason, the Bank evaluated the robustness
of frameworks to different economic shocks and behavioural assumptions.
Understandability: Monetary policy works best when it is well understood.
The implications for communications and credibility are important, even if
difficult to measure. The public consultations and laboratory experiments
were essential for this part of the evaluation.
To perform well for all these criteria, a monetary policy framework must be
able to keep inflation expectations well anchored. The anchoring of inflation
expectations under FIT has allowed the Bank to react aggressively when
necessary and to take into account employment and other considerations
beyond inflation. Without well-anchored inflation expectations, monetary
policy would need to focus much more strictly on keeping inflation on
target.
47
47 Modern economic theory and empirical evidence indicate that inflation expectations are the main factor
influencing inflation. By keeping inflation expectations well anchored at target, monetary policy can maintain
inflation close to that target. Moreover, when inflation expectations are well anchored, movements in the policy
rate translate more directly into changes in the real interest rate, strengthening the effectiveness of monetary
policy.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 39
Analytical approaches
The Bank conducted most of the analysis of macroeconomic performance
using the Terms-of-Trade Economic Model (ToTEM), one of the Bank’s main
models of the Canadian economy (Corrigan et al. 2021).
48
Many of ToTEM’s
parameters are estimated to match the historical dynamics of the Canadian
economy. Notably, ToTEM’s structural equations assume that a significant
fraction of price- and wage-setters base their expectations on rules of thumb,
while the remainder act rationally. The importance of rule-of-thumb
behaviour undermines the performance of highly history-dependent
frameworks such as PLT and NGDP-level targeting. In contrast, FIT, AIT and
the dual mandate all perform relatively well in ToTEM (Dorich, Mendes and
Zhang 2021; Swarbrick and Zhang, forthcoming).
Given the central role private sector expectations play in how well history-
dependent frameworks perform, the Bank conducted additional analysis using
purpose-built models. Wagner, Schlanger and Zhang (forthcoming) compare
the performance of alternative frameworks in a model with bounded
rationality, or “cognitive discounting.”
49
They confirm the ToTEM results
regarding the underperformance of highly history-dependent frameworks.
Amano et al. (2020) study the optimal degree of history dependence under
AIT in a model where some firms have adaptive expectations. They find that
the best time frame for targeting average inflation is slightly less than two
years.
The Bank also conducted laboratory experiments to evaluate people’s ability
to forecast inflation and output under different frameworks (Kostyshyna,
Petersen and Yang, forthcoming). Actual inflation and output outcomes are
determined using a simple New Keynesian model, conditional on subjects’
median forecasts. Results suggest that FIT and the dual mandate are the most
stabilizing regimes, followed by AIT. Highly history-dependent policies
performed poorly.
ToTEM is not well suited for assessing the implications of alternative
frameworks for the distribution of income, wealth or consumption. For this
reason, the Bank used a heterogeneous agent New Keynesian model to assess
48 Technical details of the model-based evaluation of macroeconomic performance are broadly in line with those
described in sections 3 and 4 in Dorich, Mendes and Zhang (2021). See also Swarbrick and Zhang (forthcoming).
49 Cognitive discounting effectively decreases the weights that agents place on events further in the future when
making decisions today (Gabaix 2020).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 40
the distributional effects of these frameworks (Djeutem, Reza and Zhang,
forthcoming).
50
In the model, income inequality is linked to the output gap.
This captures the tendency for a rise in inequality to occur during recessions.
Djeutem, Reza and Zhang (forthcoming) find that highly history-dependent
frameworks cause inequality to vary more widely throughout the business
cycle.
Analyzing the financial stability implications of a monetary policy framework
continues to be challenging. Researchers at the Bank and elsewhere are
actively studying how to integrate financial vulnerabilities into
macroeconomic models, but no single, best model has yet been developed.
For this reason, the Bank relied on the existing literature to assess the financial
stability implications of alternative frameworks. In addition, Bank staff looked
at indicators from model simulations, such as the frequency and length of
periods with very low interest rates that could fuel risk-taking behaviours.
Comparing the performance of alternative frameworks with
flexible inflation targeting
Each of the alternative frameworks exhibits different strengths and
weaknesses. Table 2 summarizes the overall performance of these
frameworks relative to a FIT framework, based on the model simulations, lab
experiments and public consultations.
51
As shown in the table, no single
framework was found to dominate across all relevant criteria, though some
proved significantly more competitive than others. The performances of these
frameworks are presented here, beginning with the two that proved most
competitive relative to FITAIT and the dual mandate.
50 The model builds on Acharya and Dogra (2020) and Acharya, Challe and Dogra (2021).
51 The results of model simulations reflect the assumptions and structure of the model in question.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 41
Table 2:
Summary of the performance of alternative frameworks compared with flexible
inflation targeting
Average inflation
targeting
Dual mandate
Price-level targeting
NGDP-level targeting
NGDP-growth targeting
Price stability
Similar to FIT
Supports inflation
during ELB
episodes
Similar to FIT
Does not materially
change the
behaviour of
inflation
Superior to FIT
Stabilizes inflation
better
Keeps average
inflation at 2 percent
Provides certainty
about the long-run
price level
Slightly inferior to FIT
Does not directly aim to
stabilize prices, so
performance depends on
the evolution of trend
output
Relative-price shocks can
lead to volatility in
consumer prices even when
the GDP deflator is stable
Inferior to FIT
Substantially increases the
volatility of inflation, largely
because of poor
stabilization of the real
economy
Stability of
real economy
Similar to FIT
Supports activity
during ELB
episodes
Can lead to greater
volatility at other
times
Similar to FIT
Performs modestly
better on
employment
Modestly greater
volatility of the
output gap
Inferior to FIT
Leads to a substantial
increase in
unconditional
volatility of output
Supports activity
during ELB episodes
Slightly inferior to FIT
Leads to an increase in
unconditional volatility of
output
Supports activity during ELB
episodes
Inferior to FIT
Responding to growth rate
rather than level of real
activity leads to a very
substantial increase in
unconditional volatility of
output and employment
Financial
stability
Slightly inferior to
FIT
Increases low-for-
long tendency
Reduces scope for
discretionary
departures from
low for long
Similar to FIT
Does not materially
affect the
frequency of
episodes with
persistently low
interest rates
Inferior to FIT
Greatly increases
low-for-long
tendency
Reduces scope for
discretionary
departures from low
for long
Similar to FIT
Reduces tendency to cut
interest rates in response to
positive supply shocks
Reduces scope for
discretionary departures
from low for long
Similar to FIT
Reduces tendency to cut
interest rates in response to
positive supply shocks
Increases macroeconomic
volatility, which could
trigger financial risks
Distributional
implications
Similar to FIT
Similar volatility of
real economy leads
to similar cyclical
variation in
inequality
Similar to FIT
Similar volatility of
real economy leads
to similar cyclical
variation in
inequality
Inferior to FIT
Greater volatility of
real economy leads
to more cyclical
variation in inequality
Inferior to FIT
Greater volatility of real
economy leads to more
cyclical variation in
inequality
Inferior to FIT
Greater volatility of real
economy leads to more
cyclical variation in
inequality
Robustness
Similar to FIT
Somewhat greater
sensitivity to nature
of expectations
formation
More robust
performance in ELB
episodes
Similar to FIT
No material
change in
sensitivity to
assumptions and
shocks
Inferior to FIT
Much greater
sensitivity to nature
of expectations
formation
Inferior to FIT
Much greater sensitivity to
nature of expectations
formation
Inferior to FIT
Deterioration in
performance in many
situations, including
recoveries from recessions
Understand-
ability
Slightly inferior to
FIT
Multi-year average
of inflation is
understandable,
but less familiar
than year-over-
year inflation
Inferior to FIT
Having two
objectives reduces
clarity and
simplicity
Difficult to quantify
employment
objective
Inferior to FIT
Price level is an
unfamiliar concept to
many
Subjects in laboratory
experiments found it
difficult to forecast
Inferior to FIT
Nominal GDP is an
unfamiliar concept to many
Subjects in laboratory
experiments found it
difficult to forecast
Inferior to FIT
Nominal GDP is an
unfamiliar concept to many
Subjects in laboratory
experiments found it
difficult to forecast
Note: ELB is effective lower bound, FIT is flexible inflation targeting, and NGDP is nominal gross domestic product.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 42
Average inflation targeting
Under AIT, the target is a multi-year average of consumer price index
inflation. This report shows results for a three-year averaging period, but Bank
staff studied several other averaging period durations. To return inflation to
the multi-year average target, a period of below-target inflation must be
followed by a period of above-target inflation, and vice versa (Figure 1).
The model simulation results suggest that the main benefit of AIT is that its
embedded history dependence allows it to perform better than FIT at the ELB.
For example, in ToTEM, the average output gap during ELB episodes is
modestly narrower at -1.5 percent under AIT, compared with -1.7 percent
under FIT. Similarly, average inflation during ELB episodes improves from
0.8 percent in FIT to 0.9 percent in AIT. Thus, when the policy rate is as low as
it can go, AIT delivers slightly better outcomes for inflation and output.
The principal difficulty with AIT is that, when not at the ELB, it can lead to
volatility in the real economy. In particular, the need to follow periods of
above-target inflation with periods of below-target inflation means that
monetary policy would sometimes have to engineer a slowdown. In models
with fully rational expectations, a short period of weakness is usually enough
because price- and wage-setters anticipate the decline in future inflation and
moderate their respective price and wage increases. In more realistic models
Flexible inflation targeting Average inflation targeting Price-level targeting
Figure 1: History-dependent frameworks involve overshooting the
inflation target after a disinflationary shock and vice versa
0 1 2 3 4 5
time
b. Price level
Disinflationary
shock
0 1 2 3 4 5
(%)
time
a. Inflation
3
2
1
Disinflationary
shock
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 43
like ToTEM, price- and wage-setters are not entirely rational, so a more severe
slowdown or recession may be needed to pull inflation down below target.
Employmentinflation dual mandate
A dual mandate has only a modest impact on employment outcomes
compared with FIT. Under FIT, the health of the labour market is central to
achieving the inflation target on a sustained basis. The model simulations
capture this through the important role that labour market developments play
in driving the output gap and wage growth.
In the Bank’s laboratory experiments, the dual mandate performed the same
as FIT and better than highly history-dependent alternatives such as PLT and
NGDP-level targeting. This suggests that subjects in the experiments had a
relatively good understanding of the dynamics under a dual mandate.
However, many participants in the Bank’s public consultations reported
finding the dual mandate somewhat more difficult to understand than FIT.
They also expressed concerns that a dual mandate could lead to higher
inflation and the politicization of monetary policy (see Box 7). These concerns
point to a risk that a dual mandate could detract from the clarity and
simplicity of the FIT frameworktwo features that have led to a strong
anchoring of inflation expectations. A de-anchoring of inflation expectations
could lead to excessive volatility in output and employment.
Price-level targeting
PLT is an extreme version of AIT. The price level reflects the entire history of
inflation, so targeting the price level is similar to targeting an infinite average
of inflation. This ensures that inflation averages 2 percent over time. The high
degree of history dependence means that PLT helps reduce the severity of
ELB episodes.
But, for the same reasons as under AIT, these gains come at the cost of
increased volatility in output and employment. The standard deviation of the
output gap rises from 1.3 percent under FIT to 1.5 percent under PLT. This, in
turn, implies more variation in inequality over the course of the business cycle.
In addition, subjects in the laboratory experiments found it difficult to forecast
in a PLT environment, and the heuristics they adopted led to destabilizing
dynamics. On balance, the costs of PLT appear to outweigh the benefits.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 44
NGDP-level targeting
NGDP-level targeting is modelled as stabilizing NGDP around a trend path.
This framework has received renewed attention because of its potential to
address some of the challenges of the current low interest rate environment
(see, e.g., Ambler 2020). Like PLT, the high degree of history dependence
inherent in NGDP-level targeting helps at the ELB but is destabilizing overall.
This framework’s macroeconomic performance is poorer than that of PLT
because of several unique characteristics:
Monetary policy’s reactions to prices and output are forced to be equal
(because NGDP is the product of the GDP price deflator and real output).
This can result in inefficient responses to shocks.
The framework implicitly reacts to output rather than the output gap,
meaning that shifts in potential output can lead to persistent deviations of
employment and output from their efficient levels. This can force
adjustment through inflation, leading to inefficient relative price
dispersion.
Even when the framework stabilizes the GDP deflator, relative price shocks
can still lead to volatility in consumer prices.
Overall, compared with FIT, NGDP-level targeting raises the volatility of
inflation, the output gap and the policy rate.
A key practical advantage of NGDP-level targeting is that it avoids the need
to estimate the unobservable level of potential output or maximum
sustainable employmentmonetary policy need only react to observed and
forecasted NGDP. This, however, must be weighed against the fact that NGDP
is measured imperfectly and revised over time. In addition, shifts in the trend
growth rate of potential output would further undermine this framework’s
performance relative to the simulation results, partly because these shifts
would exert persistent, growing impacts on the price level.
NGDP-level targeting also has implications for financial stability. By stabilizing
nominal income, central banks can help improve the risk-sharing properties of
non-contingent debt contracts, such as mortgages or vehicle loans, thereby
improving financial stability outcomes (Sheedy 2014; Bullard and DiCecio
2019). This framework also has advantages when dealing with positive
productivity shocks. Under NGDP-level targeting, the increase in output
counterbalances the incentive to ease monetary policy stemming from lower
prices. In contrast, under FIT, inflation and the output gap would both call for
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 45
lower rates after a positive productivity shock, potentially increasing the
incentives for risk taking and debt accumulation. However, these benefits
must be set against the need to return nominal income to some target path.
This need can sometimes limit a central bank’s ability to depart from a low-
for-long policy even if the real economy has recovered and financial stability
concerns have become more prominent.
NGDP-growth targeting
Targeting the growth rate of NGDP leads to very poor macroeconomic
outcomes. This is due primarily to the performance of this framework in
recoveries. After a recession, growth can be strong even though the level of
output remains depressed. So, reacting to the growth rate of NGDP leads to
premature tightening of monetary policy, which would cut short a recovery
and stifle job growth.
Lessons from the horse race
Overall, the results of the horse race suggest that FIT, AIT and the dual
mandate are likely to perform better than PLT and both types of NGDP
targeting. This is consistent with the findings from the Bank’s public
consultations, where respondents viewed FIT, AIT and the dual mandate as
the most promising frameworks.
While these three frameworks all perform relatively well in several ways, none
dominates. Moreover, the differences in performance between these
frameworks are small, suggesting that any gains from a change in framework
would be modest. Nevertheless, two important lessons emerged from the
horse race.
Lesson 1: Nearly all the benefits of average inflation targeting are
at the effective lower bound
Under history-dependent frameworks like AIT, inflation is generally allowed to
rise temporarily above the target after an ELB episode. The anticipation of the
low-for-long policy rate required to generate this overshoot provides stimulus
when it is needed most during the ELB episode. However, when not at the
ELB, plausible departures from rational expectations, such as rule-of-thumb
strategies, can make history-dependent frameworks destabilizing.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 46
This raises the question of whether the benefits of history dependence could
be captured at the ELB without adopting a new framework. One approach
would be to use the type of state-contingent forward guidance analyzed by
Mendes and Murchison (2014). While AIT involves a commitment about the
path of inflation, a guidance-based approach would involve a commitment
about the path of the policy rate. Such guidance can be implemented in many
ways, so the details could be tailored to a given situation.
The Bank’s response to the COVID-19 crisis provides an example of this type
of guidance. The commitment to hold the policy rate at the ELB “until
economic slack is absorbed so that the 2 percent inflation target is sustainably
achieved” signalled the Bank’s intention to maintain monetary policy stimulus
longer than strictly required to achieve the inflation target. This approach uses
the flexibility of the FIT framework to provide additional stimulus without
committing to make up for past misses of the inflation target. Nevertheless,
communicating and exercising such “patience” would qualitatively mimic
some features of AIT. Analysis by Bank staff confirms that providing this type
of state-contingent guidance whenever the policy rate reaches the ELB can
deliver some of the key benefits of AIT (Chu and Zhang, forthcoming). This
approach keeps average inflation closer to 2 percent and improves inflation,
output and employment outcomes when the ELB is binding. Like AIT, this
approach would result more often in inflation rising temporarily above the
target after being below it for a period.
Lesson 2: A dual mandate only modestly affects employment
The economy’s performance under a dual mandate is similar to that under the
current FIT framework. Bank staff came to this conclusion using the standard
assumption that the levels of both potential output and maximum sustainable
employment are known to policy-makers. However, in reality, they are
unknown and inherently uncertain. As discussed in Chapter 3, major ongoing
structural changes to labour markets due to shifting demographics,
globalization and technological change accentuate this uncertainty.
Incorporating this uncertainty and the learning process of policy-makers into
the models used in the horse race is challenging. For this reason, Carter and
Mendes (forthcoming) develop a simple model that captures key aspects of
this learning process. One of their main findings is that the central bank tends
to learn more about the true levels of potential output and maximum
sustainable employment when the economy is operating above its productive
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 47
capacity. This is because during these periods, the sensitivity of inflation to
economic activity tends to be relatively high, making inflation outcomes more
informative.
This finding suggests that allowing the economy to temporarily operate
above current estimates of its productive capacity can help policy-makers
learn about the appropriateness of those estimates. By doing this, monetary
policy is in effect probing for or seeking the maximum sustainable level of
employment. Carter and Mendes (forthcoming) show that policy frameworks
with this type of probing feature can yield some benefits. In particular, under
certain circumstances it can reduce the uncertainty surrounding the true levels
of potential output and maximum sustainable employment, which then
contributes to improved macroeconomic outcomes. However, these benefits
must be weighed against the costs. Probing may sometimes lead to inflation
temporarily rising above the target and could contribute to de-anchoring
inflation expectations.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 48
Chapter 5: Overview of monetary policy
tools
The Bank of Canada conducts monetary policy to achieve the objectives set
out in its inflation-control agreement with the Government of Canada and has
a number of monetary policy tools to do so.
The most commonly used is the policy rate, which influences the interest rates
that financial institutions use to set borrowing costs for households and
businesses. The Bank typically uses other tools only when the policy rate is at
the effective lower bound (ELB). Several of these other tools are outlined in
the Bank’s Framework for Conducting Monetary Policy at Low Interest Rates
(Bank of Canada 2015). They include extensions to how the Bank uses both
the policy rate and its balance sheet to affect other key borrowing rates in the
economy.
In Canada, the policy rate has fallen to the assessed ELB only twice, first
during the 2008–09 global financial crisis and more recently during the
COVID-19 pandemic (see Chapter 2). The Bank deployed additional tools
during the pandemic (Box 8), in some cases for the first time. While central
banks in several other jurisdictions have used a wider range of tools to
provide stimulus on various occasions in recent decades, Canadians may be
less familiar with some of these tools. But all of the Bank’s monetary policy
tools serve the same objective: to provide the appropriate degree of
monetary stimulus in order to achieve the Bank’s inflation target.
Box 8:
The Bank of Canada’s response to the COVID-19
pandemic
In normal times, the Bank of Canada delivers or withdraws stimulus as needed by
adjusting the policy rate. But the impact of the COVID-19 pandemic was
unprecedented, and it called for extraordinary action.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 49
The Bank took a range of swift and decisive actions to help mitigate the impact of
the pandemic on the Canadian financial system and economy. Specifically, the Bank
did this by:
52
launching liquidity facilities and programs to support the functioning of financial
markets so that households, businesses and governments could continue to
access credit (most of these facilities and programs were discontinued as market
functioning improved)
lowering the policy rate to 0.25 percentthe effective lower bound (ELB)—in
March 2020 and, beginning in July 2020, using forward guidance to communicate
that the policy rate would be maintained at the ELB until economic slack is
absorbed so that the 2 percent inflation target is sustainably achieved
using quantitative easing (QE) to supplement and reinforce the reductions in the
policy rate and forward guidance by also helping keep longer-term borrowing
rates low
Re-establishing market functioning
The Bank’s first priority at the onset of the pandemic was to restore and maintain
smooth functioning of the financial markets essential to Canadians. When
widespread selling pressures caused liquidity to dry up sharply in multiple key
funding markets, the Bank rolled out several new facilities. These facilities were
effective in countering important strains and restoring well-functioning markets
(Fontaine et al. 2020; Gravelle 2021a).
53
For example, to bolster the capacity of commercial banks and other financial
institutions to support businesses’ short-term credit needs, the Bank launched a
facility to buy bankers’ acceptances. Spreads on bankers’ acceptances over
corresponding rates for overnight index swaps fell by 15 basis points on the day of
the announcement and by up to 70 basis points over a longer period (Arora et al.
2020).
Other programs to support short-term funding markets included the Commercial
Paper Purchase Program, which provided funding for a wide range of firms and
financial institutions, and the Provincial Money Market Purchase Program.
The Bank also targeted market functioning through the Provincial Bond Purchase
Program and Corporate Bond Purchase Program. These programs helped narrow
spreads that had widened considerably in March 2020. Both programs were relatively
small and were not considered a meaningful source of monetary stimulus. A year
52 For more details on the Bank’s actions during the pandemic, please see the Bank’s website.
53 The Bank’s purchases helped rebalance the lopsided trading flows in key debt markets, allowing buyers and
sellers to set prices. Also, because securities dealers have limited room for risk on their own balance sheets, the
Bank’s purchases helped free up dealers’ capacity to provide liquidity in these markets.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 50
after they were introduced, both programs were allowed to expire on schedule. Debt
markets had become fully functional again, with credit spreads for most borrowers
either at or below pre-pandemic levels.
The Bank also started making large-scale purchases of Government of Canada (GoC)
bonds in the secondary market through the Government of Canada Bond Purchase
Program (GBPP). When the program was first launched, the purchases mostly helped
improve liquidity, ensuring that the GoC bond market and, in turn, other debt
markets could work smoothly (Fontaine, Ford and Walton 2020). Once the program
was announced, yields on GoC bonds with less than three years to maturity fell by
about 15 basis points, with the yield curve about 10 basis points lower on average
(Arora et al. 2021).
54
Scaling stimulus to the shock as appropriate
Once market stresses dissipated, the focus of the GBPP shifted from restoring market
functioning to providing additional monetary policy stimulusthrough quantitative
easingand reinforcing the messaging of the Bank’s outcome-based forward
guidance.
The Bank also stopped buying short-term GoC bonds because yields on those bonds
were well anchored by forward guidance. Forward guidance and QE have been
complementary throughout the pandemic, with forward guidance keeping shorter-
term yields low and QE lowering yields of longer maturities.
By putting downward pressure on bond yields and lending rates throughout the
financial system, forward guidance and QE lowered borrowing costs for households,
businesses and governments.
Low borrowing costs and well-functioning financial markets helped businesses adjust
to the pandemic and supported household spending. This positive experience has
demonstrated that the Bank can use different monetary policy tools effectively to
help stimulate demand even once the policy rate is at the ELB, and to help return
inflation to the target sustainably. The Bank will continue to assess the impact of
different monetary tools used to meet its mandate.
54
As well, in a daily purchase operation, $1 billion of GoC bond purchases caused an average decline in yields of
about 0.8 basis points on purchased bondsa decline of about 1.1 basis points in two-year and five-year
operations, i.e., the flow effect. For additional details, see Arora et al. (2021).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 51
Transmission channels
Adjustments to monetary policy reach different parts of the economy through
five main transmission channels.
Interest rate channel: Monetary policy tools work through this channel by
affecting market interest rates and bond yields. It is sometimes called the
credit channel.
55
Exchange rate channel: Changes to the level of interest rates or yields
relative to those of other countries can affect the exchange rate.
Signalling channel: Through the signalling channel, a central bank can
influence expectations about future policy actions, thereby lowering
longer-term rates and reducing uncertainty. The signalling channel can
reinforce the interest rate channel.
Liquidity channel: By purchasing financial assets, a central bank can make
it easier for buyers and sellers to carry out transactions in markets. This
helps ensure that the other transmission channels work as intended.
Portfolio balance channel: By purchasing financial assets, central banks
can affect the quantity and mix of financial assets available to investors.
Changes to the available supply of assets, or to the amount of risk in the
financial system, can lead to a repricing of those assets.
The state of the economy and financial system affects the strength of each
channel and the impact of the policy tool being used (Figure 2). As well, the
effectiveness of each channel depends on economic conditions and on the
specific tool.
The size and structure of a country’s economy are also key factors. For
instance, in small open economies such as Canada, the exchange rate channel
tends to be more important than it is for economies with large internal
markets. At the same time, it also implies that interest rates further out the
yield curve are heavily influenced by the global forces.
55 The credit channel can also involve how monetary policy affects the quantity of credit available, rather than the
price.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 52
Monetary policy action
Risk-free interest rates of various maturities
Household and business borrowing rates
Aggregate demand
Output/labour gap
Inflation
Expected inflation
Exchange rates
Figure 2: The transmission channels of monetary policy
Monetary policy tools and how they work
When not constrained by the ELB, the Bank usually conducts monetary policy
by raising, lowering or maintaining the policy rate. At the ELB, the Bank may
deploy other tools to provide additional stimulus given that the policy rate
cannot be lowered any further. With ELB episodes now more likely (see the
discussion in Chapter 3 on lower neutral interest rates), other monetary policy
tools will need to be used more often.
Liquidity channel
Signalling channel
Interest rate channel
Portfolio balance
channel
Liquidity channel
Exchange rate
channel
Financial system
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 53
Some of these tools are extensions of the Bank’s main approach to providing
stimulusthe policy ratewhile others work through the explicit use of
central bank balance sheets.
56
Extensions of the policy rate
When the policy rate is at the ELB and further stimulus is needed to meet the
inflation objective, the Bank can go beyond its typical approach in two ways.
The Bank can either maintain the rate but help set expectations that it will
remain low for an extended period, or it can, on an exceptional basis, reduce
the policy rate into negative territory.
Forward guidance involves conditional statements or commitments about the
future path of policy rates. Central banks typically use these statements to
indicate that policy rates will be held at the ELB for a longer period than
historical patterns would suggest. Forward guidance can be purely calendar-
basedreferring to a specific month or yearor outcome-based (also known
as state-contingent), often tied to the economic or inflation outlook.
Outcome-based forward guidance can also be connected to calendar-based
guidance through projections of when the economic outcomes are expected
to be achieved. Forward guidance therefore works primarily through the
signalling channelaffecting expectations and reducing uncertaintyand
provides additional stimulus by lowering relatively short-term yields.
Nominal policy rates can be negative, but there are limits. For example,
deposits will be converted to cash at some point. This is sometimes referred
to as the switch-to-cash rate.
57
Lowering the policy rate below the switch-to-
cash rate could impair financial markets, reducing the effectiveness of
monetary policy actions.
Balance sheet tools
Using balance sheet tools—a broad category of measuresthe central bank
directly intervenes in financial markets to affect interest rates and borrowing
costs for consumers and businesses. In this sense, these tools have a similar
objective to that of the policy rate, but they may work through different
channels. The most common balance sheet tools used for providing
56 See the Bank’s guiding principles for central bank intervention for more information.
57 Witmer and Yang (2016), for example, estimate that the switch-to-cash rate in Canada has been -50 basis points
in the past. The switch-to-cash rate is a distinct concept from the reversal interest rate, which is the rate at which
accommodative monetary policy becomes contractionary for lending (Brunnermeier and Koby 2018).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 54
additional policy stimulus involve central banksbuying financial assets,
usually sovereign government bonds. This increases the demand for the
assets, pushing up their price and putting downward pressure on their yields.
Because government bonds serve as the pricing benchmark for other debt,
lower yields on government bonds translate into reduced borrowing costs,
not just for governments but also for consumers and businesses.
Whether central banks are buying government or private sector debt, asset
purchases provide stimulus through three features:
the flow of purchases
the total expected stock of purchases
the composition of purchases
Quantitative easing (QE) involves the central bank buying longer-term
government (or government-guaranteed) bonds. When conducting QE,
central banks announce a target level of purchaseseither a total amount or
a pace (e.g., a target amount per week)and the expected composition.
As noted, large regularly occurring government bond purchases provide
stimulus by putting downward pressure on government bond yields. This
helps lower borrowing costs across a range of securities through the interest
rate channel because yields on government bonds serve as benchmark rates
for other funding markets. When these markets are working well, QE works
similarly to changes in the policy rate, although QE’s main effects are on
longer-term interest rates. QE also works through the portfolio balance
channel because central bank purchases reduce the relative amount of
government bonds available for investors to buy. This causes them to
reallocate their holdings toward riskier debt. If these actions spur reallocation
across global portfolios, effects may occur through the exchange rate channel
as well.
During periods of financial stress, government bond purchases can also help
repair the liquidity channel, making it easier for buyers and sellers to conduct
transactions because the central bank acts as a price-insensitive buyer.
58
Increases in settlement balances (or central bank reserves) fund these
purchases. Settlement balances are interest-bearing central bank liabilities,
and when they increase as a result of QE, these increases are not permanent.
58 In some cases, central banks may also purchase sub-sovereign government debt as part of a QE program.
However, this is more typically aimed at restoring liquidity if these markets are impaired.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 55
This temporary feature clearly distinguishes QE from monetization of
government debt.
59
Yield curve targeting is similar to QE and works through the same channels,
but it focuses directly on the level of bond yields rather than on the quantity
of purchases. The central bank announces a target level for a specific yield,
typically at the middle of the yield curve, and stands ready to purchase
sufficient bonds to achieve that target level.
Credit easing involves purchases of non-government debt, such as corporate
bonds. These purchases reduce borrowing rates for those who rely on
market-based financing, which are typically priced at a spread over the yield
of a government bond of the same maturity. During a crisis period,
purchasing these bonds eases borrowing costs by repairing the liquidity
channel.
Credit easing can also provide stimulus through the portfolio balance and
exchange rate channels, similar to how QE provides stimulus through those
respective channels.
Collateralized lending provides financial institutions an opportunity to lock in
liquidity over the medium term, typically a one- to three-year horizon.
Examples include fixed-rate longer-term repurchase agreements (repos)
conducted at the policy rate. These programs help reinforce forward guidance
through the liquidity and signalling channels.
60
Funding for lending involves central bank provision of funding to commercial
banks at below-market rates, contingent on the banks increasing lending to
targeted borrowers. Typically aimed at small and medium-sized businesses
who rely heavily on bank financing, funding for lending programs work
primarily through the interest rate channel. Examples of such programs
include the targeted longer-term refinancing operations conducted by the
European Central Bank and the Bank of England’s Term Funding Scheme with
additional incentives for small or medium-sized businesses.
59 Beaudry (2020b) offers a more comprehensive description of the Bank’s QE program. An explainer entitled
Understanding Quantitative Easing” is also available on the Bank’s website.
60 The Bank of Canada used term repos to reinforce its conditional commitment in April 2009, when it conducted
6- and 12-month term repos at the target rate.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 56
Effectiveness of monetary policy tools
Changes to the policy rate are acknowledged as the most effective and best
understood policy tool. The presence of an ELB, however, means that central
banks may need other tools when the policy rate cannot be lowered further
and additional monetary stimulus is needed. These tools are not perfect
substitutes for changes to the policy ratetheir impact on economic activity
is less well understood. Nevertheless, evidence suggests that all of the
monetary policy tools discussed above can be effective in easing financial
conditions, which stimulates total demand and helps return inflation to target.
Monetary policy tools will be more effective if they are well understoodand,
as much as possible, acceptedby the public. Almost three-quarters of
respondents to a Bank consultation said they would not support the Bank
using negative interest rates (Bank of Canada 2021). Participants were more in
favour of the Bank using other tools: most indicated they support the Bank’s
QE program, and about two-thirds indicated support for forward guidance.
Johnson et al. (2020) provide an extensive literature review on which tools
work best and when.
Some key takeaways:
Forward guidance commitments have proven to be effective at providing
additional easing by lowering shorter-term yields.
Balance sheet tools such as QE and yield curve targeting appear to be
useful complements to forward guidance. All three mitigate negative
macroeconomic shocks by lowering medium- and longer-term yields.
Credit easing and funding for lending are more targeted tools that have
been used effectively to restore market functioning in the financial system
and to increase access to credit.
Central banks in some jurisdictions have provided additional monetary
stimulus by lowering policy rates into negative territory. Empirical
evidence, however, suggests that policy rate reductions become
progressively less stimulativeeven when rates are still slightly above
zeroand may even reach a point where they become contractionary.
As noted above, the size and structure of an economy can affect how effective
each tool is in a given situation. In small open economies such as Canada, QE
affects both the level of domestic yields relative to global yields as well as
exchange rates. In addition, when faced with a global shock, small open
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 57
economies may also be affected by the policy actions that their larger trading
partners take. For example, when the US Federal Reserve conducts QE, global
term premiums decline, resulting in lower term premiums on Government of
Canada bonds as well.
The health of the financial system matters. Certain tools have their greatest
impact when markets are impaired because part of what they do is improve
market functioning. But the structure of the financial system and relative
importance of different types of financial intermediaries also matter. For
example, purchases of private sector assets such as corporate bonds are more
likely to work better in jurisdictions where businesses tend to fund themselves
in markets and where financial assets are held as a source of wealth. Similarly,
jurisdictions that rely more on bank-based lending may benefit more from
programs such as funding for lending, which aim to stimulate demand by
giving banks incentive to make certain loans.
The role of other public financial institutions can be important for the
effectiveness of different tools while other non-monetary policy actions are
being taken. In Canada, Export Development Canada (EDC) and Business
Development Canada (BDC) are well-established Crown corporations that
provide funding to domestically based exporters and to small and medium-
sized businesses, respectively.
61
The federal government has used EDC and
BDC during crises to provide low-cost funding directly to businesses. So, the
impact of a funding for lending program in Canada could be much lower than
in countries that lack similar institutions.
In addition, some non-monetary policy actions can complement and reinforce
certain monetary policy tools, increasing overall effectiveness of economic
support policies.
62
For example, easing microprudential policies can facilitate
the portfolio balance channel of asset purchase programs (see Basel
Committee on Banking Supervision 2021).
Taking all of this context into account is important when assessing the tools’
ultimate impact. Moreover, multiple tools might be used at the same time,
61 Another key Canadian public financial institution is the Farm Credit Corporation, which provides financial services
to farms and other agricultural operations in Canada.
62 The effectiveness of other policies can also depend on monetary policy actions. For instance, simulations of
structural macroeconomic models suggest that fiscal multipliers are larger when monetary policy holds rates flat
at the ELB (De Resende, Lalonde and Snudden 2010). Miyamoto, Nguyen and Sergeyev (2018) and Ramey and
Zubairy (2018) provide supporting empirical evidence for Japan and the United States, respectively
.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 58
working through overlapping channels. So, the interactions among them must
also be considered when assessing the effectiveness of any one tool.
While academic discussion of balance sheet tools tends to focus on the size of
purchases and its impact on yields, looking at operational considerations is
also important. For instance, as asset purchases expand central banks’ balance
sheets, they also increase the central bank’s exposure to financial losses.
Appropriate policies governing the capacity for the central bank to absorb
financial losses, such as larger capital levels or financial reserves, are therefore
needed to support the credibility of asset purchase programs.
63
This provides
the central bank with a level of financial independence that helps support its
delegated operational independence to meet its inflation-targeting mandate.
And, to offset market functioning risks associated with a scarcity of some
assets in the market, securities lending and repo operations usually need to
be expanded to make the central bank’s asset holdings more readily available
to private investors.
Because monetary policy works to stimulate the economy by influencing
interest rates and asset prices, some analysts in Canada and elsewhere have
questioned whether some policy actions may also increase inequality.
Reductions in the level of interest rates and use of other monetary policy
tools can boost wealth by increasing the value of assets, such as the
investments that Canadians have in their registered retirement savings plans
or company pension plans. Given that these assets are not distributed evenly
across society, monetary policy can sometimes widen wealth inequality. Still,
by reducing cyclical swings in growth and employment, monetary policy
actions can help reduce income inequality, mainly by supporting a healthier
labour market that creates more jobs (Macklem 2012; 2021). The effects of
monetary policy actions on individual households can vary considerably,
though (Box 9). The Bank will continue to work to more fully understand the
impact of the policy rate as well as other monetary policy tools, such as QE,
on both income and wealth inequality in Canada.
63 See, for example, Stella (1997).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 59
Box 9:
Monetary policy and inequality
Before the 200809 global financial crisis, considerations related to inequality were
not at the forefront of the analysis of monetary policy. Distributional effects across
industries, income groups and occupations generally received less weight because
changes to the policy rate were seen as having broad effects on the whole economy.
Indeed, uneven effects that might have resulted from easing would typically be
reversed by the subsequent tightening.
In the years since the 200809 global financial crisis, though, there has been greater
emphasis on how monetary policy can affect inequality.
64
Countercyclical monetary
policy can help limit job losses and reduce the depth and duration of periods of
economic weakness. And, in doing so, monetary policy can reduce labour income
inequality to the extent that long periods of unemployment, especially for less-skilled
or low-wage workers, can have lasting effects on earning potential. Reaching
maximum sustainable employment is consistent with inflation targeting because
inflation can be kept on target sustainably only after excess capacity in the economy,
including in the labour market, has been absorbed.
Monetary policy’s impact on wealth inequality is more complicated. The long-
standing argument that monetary policy is neutral when evaluated over an entire
business cycle is harder to make when, as has been the case in many jurisdictions,
policy rates are kept close to their lower bound for several years. In addition, credit
easing—which has been used extensively as an ELB tool by central banks outside
Canadais often perceived as tilted to benefit specific sectors.
Generally, monetary policy tools are blunt instruments that have broad effects.
Nevertheless, considering the transmission channels that policy tools work through is
important when evaluating potential differences in their effects on various segments
of the economy.
For instance, a change in interest rates has different effects on:
savers versus borrowers
those with existing debt versus those taking on new debt
those with savings in assets such as housing, bonds and equities versus those
with savings accounts at banks and other financial institutions
This is true regardless of whether the change in interest rates is caused by a change
to the policy rate, forward guidance or balance sheet tools, although the latter may
64 In previous renewals, the Bank examined the redistributive effects of different levels of steady-state inflation
(Bank of Canada 2011) and those arising from a transition between steady-state inflation rates (Bank of Canada
2015). This analysis found that changes in inflation can have significant redistributive effects across different age,
income and wealth groups.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 60
have greater effects on targeted asset classes. In addition, whatever the tool, the
effects depend on the actual and perceived length of the change in interest ratesor
of asset purchases or other balance sheet or policy actionsand on whether savers
and borrowers face fixed or variable interest rates.
As well, some effects are almost instantaneous, while others are delayed. A large
proportion of consumer interest ratesfor example, on mortgages, vehicle loans and
credit cardsare fixed. In these cases, it may take some time for existing borrowers
to see any benefit from a reduction in the policy rate, for instance. Similarly, the
nature of a savings product affects how much a saver benefits (or suffers) from a
change in the policy rate. Those with fixed-rate products could see little impact, while
those with variable-rate products or riskier assets may see more of an immediate
gain or loss.
The longer rates are expected to remain low, the larger the potential impact on the
prices of assets such as bonds, equities or housing. The impact on housing prices, in
particular, is often largely driven by the fact that demand for housing goes up
whenever borrowing costs go down. An initial outsized gain in house prices could
fuel expectations that such outsized gains will continue indefinitely, spurring investor
and speculative demand. But since more houses can be built, the impact on house
prices from low rates ultimately depends on how long the elevated demand lasts,
what is driving it and how long it takes to boost supply.
Monetary policythrough both changes to the policy rate and the use of balance
sheet toolsis therefore more likely to directly affect the wealth of those who
already have savings invested in bonds, equities and housing. While the easing and
tightening stages of the policy cycle may offset each other over time, the prolonged
period of low interest rates since the 200809 global financial crisis has led many to
see monetary policy as tilted toward asset holders and, as such, contributing to an
increase in wealth inequality. In contrast, the positive impact on jobs and income
inequality is less direct and can be harder to observe. This makes the overall impact
on individuals hard to determine given the differences in how Canadians accumulate
and manage their savings.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 61
Choosing tools and sequencing their use
The Bank applies tools in ways that are best suited to the nature of the
economic or financial shock. For example, academic literature and historical
experience suggest a baseline sequence for providing monetary stimulus to
respond to a negative shock to aggregate demand. Assuming that financial
markets are not impaired, a likely sequencing of policy would be the
following:
Lower the policy rate, including to the ELB if economic and financial
conditions warrant it.
Once at the ELB, use forward guidance to influence market expectations
and reduce uncertainty.
Proceed with QE, if needed, to reinforce the forward guidance and provide
additional stimulus.
Proceed with credit easing if further monetary policy stimulus is needed.
The larger the desired policy response, the quicker the central bank will
implement the different tools. For example, for a sufficiently large shock,
forward guidance and QE could be rolled out at the same time as the policy
rate is lowered to the ELB.
65
The baseline sequence above will not always be appropriate and therefore is
not predetermined. In any scenario where multiple monetary policy tools may
be needed, the contextincluding how a crisis evolves and any challenges to
the recoveryinfluences the sequencing. Assuming the policy rate is at the
ELB, and given that the effectiveness of any given tool depends on the
context, the Bank considers the following when deciding what to use and
when:
the size, duration and nature of the shock
the health of the Canadian and international financial systems
the amount of additional monetary policy easing needed and existing
policy space for each tool
how a tool would complement and interact with other monetary policy
tools as well as with other domestic and international policies
implications for financial system vulnerabilities
65 Zhang et al. (2021) find that the policy mix that delivers the best outcome for the Canadian economy calls for
immediately implementing forward guidance and QE, followed by credit easing when containment measures are
lifted.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 62
a communications strategy that provides different levels of detail for
different audiences and considers public acceptance of, and reputational
risk related to, the use of a given tool
considerations around adjustments to programs once they have been
implemented
If the transmission channels are not functioning well, monetary policy will
have less or even no impact. Central banks can therefore use balance sheet
tools to improve market functioning and help restore the transmission
mechanism. When used for these purposes, pricing of these tools is
structured to serve in a backstop capacitythat is, they are only attractive to
market participants when markets are under stress. As conditions improve,
using them becomes relatively more expensive, so demand for them wanes.
However, when balance sheet tools are used explicitly to provide monetary
stimulus, programs are designed, scaled and calibrated to achieve the
monetary policy objective (i.e., the inflation target). Unlike backstop pricing
used for market functioning operations, the use of balance sheet tools for
monetary stimulus includes the explicit intention to influence market interest
rates. Central banks announce the size and composition of their intended
asset purchases, and transactions take place at prices determined in financial
markets. Decisions to adjust program detailssuch as expanding or reducing
a program’s sizeare part of the monetary policy decision-making process.
Programs continue until the policy objective is achieved.
How tools interact with each other is important when considering how to
sequence them. As noted earlier, QE and yield curve targeting both
complement forward guidance, so the use and calibration of either can be
considered alongside forward guidance. For example, forward guidance and
QE can be combined to put downward pressure on yields across the curve
because each tool affects different maturities. In the case of yield curve
targeting, date-based forward guidance can be aligned with the term of the
yield that is being targeted. In contrast, pairing yield curve targeting with
outcome-based forward guidance poses communication challenges because
the targeted yield may arrive before the targeted economic outcome, or vice
versa.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 63
Normalization
Ultimately, monetary policy is countercyclical. Just as central banks add
stimulus when total demand is weak, less stimulus is needed as the economy
improves. This has been the approach to conducting monetary policy with the
policy rate. However, central banks have less experience with reducing or
unwinding the stimulus provided using balance sheet tools such as
quantitative easing.
When unwinding this stimulus, central banks need to take deliberate policy
actions that are guided by the economic outlook and monetary policy
objectivesparticularly the inflation outlookbut in a way that also
maintains well-functioning markets. Economic and financial conditions and
the inflation outlook influence decisions about:
when and how to slow the pace of purchases
how long to maintain a stable amount of asset holdings
when and how quickly to unwind the monetary stimulus
the long-run level and composition of the balance sheet
The normalization phase is unlikely to follow the same path as the stimulus
phase. Normalization will likely be a more gradual process than adding
stimulus. As well, the policy tools used would not necessarily be unwound in
the reverse sequence of how they were implemented.
In general, as the economic outlook improves and less additional stimulus is
warranted, central banks will proceed in gradual and measured phases. One
likely sequence for a central bank that is using QE would start with
maintaining the policy rate at the ELB while gradually reducing the
incremental amount of its asset purchases.
66
As the recovery progresses, the central bank will eventually decide conditions
no longer warrant adding any additional stimulus through QE. Over this
period, it would purchase new bonds only with proceeds from maturing
bonds, thereby keeping the overall holdings of bonds on the balance sheet
constant. This is known as the reinvestment phaseit ensures that the
amount of stimulus remains the same over a period.
Once conditions warrant reducing the amount of monetary policy stimulus, a
central bank would likely begin by lifting its policy rate from the ELB.
66
A central bank would typically not lift the policy rate from the ELB while continuing to increase its asset holdings.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 64
To further reduce the stimulus in the system, the central bank could allow
maturing assets to roll off its balance sheet. Or, for a more aggressive
approach, it could actively shrink the balance sheet by selling the assets.
Bottom line
Central banks are increasingly using a broad range of policy tools to achieve
monetary policy objectives and will likely have to continue to do so because
of the low global neutral interest rate environment.
Choosing the appropriate tools and determining the sequence of their use
requires careful consideration. In particular, central banks will need to assess
the context, including:
the nature of the shocks that they are responding to
how well the various monetary policy transmission channels are
working
what synergies among tools would be most effective in a given set of
circumstances
Fundamentally, though, monetary policy is intended to be countercyclical. As
the economy improves, less monetary stimulus will be needed to meet the
inflation objective. Just as with the initiation of various tools, actions to
unwind these tools will be guided by the economic outlook in order to
achieve the inflation target.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 65
Chapter 6: Strengthening the conduct
of monetary policy
Since 1991, monetary policy has operated within a flexible inflation-targeting
(FIT) framework. Over the past 30 years, both the framework and the
implementation of monetary policy have evolved to respond to structural
changes in the global and Canadian economies and to the evolution of
economic thinking. The flexibility inherent in the framework has allowed for
this evolution while keeping inflation low and stable and maintaining well-
anchored inflation expectations. In addition, monetary policy has made an
important contribution to the overall resilience of the Canadian economy.
Both the 200809 global financial crisis and the COVID-19 pandemic had a
significant impact on the global economy and financial system. And major
trends such as shifting demographics, new digital technologies and climate
change are altering the economic landscape. As discussed in Chapter 3, two
developments are particularly relevant to the conduct of monetary policy:
Neutral interest rates are lower than in the past and are likely to remain
low. Consequently, central banks will have less room to lower the policy
rate in the face of big negative shocks to the economy. As a result, they
will need to use other monetary policy tools more often. Otherwise,
prolonged periods with the policy rate at the effective lower bound (ELB)
could result in inflation remaining below 2 percent.
Shifting demographics, technological change, globalization and shifts in
the nature of work have had profound effects on the Canadian labour
market. These forces have made it harder to gauge the level of maximum
sustainable employment, which is the highest level of employment that
the economy can sustain before inflationary pressures build. In addition,
there is an observed weakness in the relationship between economic slack
and inflation, which has become more evident as inflation expectations
have become more firmly anchored.
Addressing these two challenges requires increased clarity in how the Bank of
Canada conducts monetary policy within the FIT framework.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 66
Targeting 2 percent inflation
Canada’s monetary policy framework will continue to target 2 percent
inflationas measured by the 12-month rate of change in the consumer price
indexwithin the 1 to 3 percent control range. The analysis conducted as part
of this review reinforces that low and stable inflation remains the appropriate
target for monetary policy. The historical success in keeping inflation low and
stable provides valuable credibility, which helps to anchor medium-term
inflation expectations. In addition, as public consultations demonstrated, FIT is
straightforward to communicate and easy to understand compared with
alternative monetary policy frameworks.
This review included a broad range of analysis and research as well as
consultations with other central banks, the economics community,
stakeholder groups and the public. Although the Bank’s horse race (see
Chapter 4) and consultations compared alternative monetary policy
frameworks from different perspectives, both concluded that FIT remains the
best framework across a range of criteria.
Feedback from the consultations demonstrated that Canadians value low and
stable inflation and that, of all the frameworks, they understand FIT the best.
Many Canadians said they want the Bank to contribute to making the
economy more inclusive, but they recognize that several non-monetary forces
affect employment and economic inclusion and that monetary policy can play
only a supporting role.
Building on the success of FIT by incorporating the potential benefits of other
frameworks in certain circumstances, the Bank will continue to leverage the
flexibility of the 1 to 3 percent inflation-control range. The goal remains to
manage the trade-off between current and future risks to the inflation target
effectively and to return inflation sustainably to target within a reasonable
time frame.
Using the flexibility of the inflation-control range and
other tools
The Bank will continue to make use of the flexibility of the 1 to 3 percent
inflation-control range, along with a broader set of tools, to help address the
challenges of structurally low interest rates. Given low global interest rates,
the policy rate will likely hit its ELB more often, and, in response, the Bank may
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 67
hold the policy rate at the ELB for an extended period. The Bank can be
patientholding rates low for longer after an ELB episodeif it assesses that
this will help return inflation sustainably to target within a reasonable time
frame.
During ELB episodes, the Bank will also need to use a broader range of
monetary policy tools more regularly to support demand and employment
and to achieve the inflation target. These include forward guidance and
balance sheet tools such as large-scale asset purchases (quantitative easing
and credit easing).
67
While experience using these tools is limited, the
evidence indicates that they effectively provide additional stimulus. However,
they are not perfect substitutes for lowering the policy rate. Thus, the ELB still
represents a constraint to providing sufficient monetary stimulus when
needed.
Chapter 4 notes that patience at the ELB combined with state-contingent
forward guidance can provide similar benefits to frameworks that depend on
history, such as average inflation targeting, without committing to making up
for past misses of the inflation target. At the ELB, the Bank’s policy rate cannot
be lowered further to stimulate additional demand. However, since many
loans (e.g., vehicle loans and mortgages) are based on long-term rates, the
Bank’s commitment to holding the policy rate low for a prolonged period can
lower the rates at which consumers and firms borrow. This can stimulate
demand and help support a quicker recovery in employment and output.
By design, a low-for-longer policy rate increases the likelihood that inflation
could modestly and temporarily overshoot the 2 percent midpoint of the
inflation-control range as the economy recovers. A commitment to holding
rates low for longer means that monetary policy will likely begin tightening
only after inflationary pressures begin to build. The benefit is that the
additional stimulus can shorten the period during which inflation remains
below target. Thus, this policy can help keep inflation and inflation
expectations close to 2 percent.
While patienceimplemented through forward guidanceis a core element
of the response during an ELB episode, the use of other monetary policy tools
may be appropriate in some circumstances. To support the effective use of
67 In rare circumstances, the Bank may also use yield curve control, funding for lending and negative interest rates
(see Chapter 5).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 68
these tools, the Bank will work with the Department of Finance Canada to
establish a framework that gives the Bank sufficient financial capacity to
manage its balance sheet to support the economy after adverse shocks and
achieve the inflation target.
Seeking maximum sustainable employment
When circumstances warrant, the Bank will refrain from raising rates pre-
emptively as inflation is approaching the 2 percent target. This will help the
Bank better assess the current level of maximum sustainable employment.
Reaching maximum sustainable employment is necessary for inflation to
remain on target, and achieving the inflation target is needed to sustain
maximum employment. The Bank will consider a broad set of labour market
and inflation indicators to guide its actions. It will not set a fixed target for
maximum sustainable employment because the precise level is unknown and
evolves over time.
Central banks have long recognized that the level of maximum sustainable
employment is unknown and time varying.
68
As discussed in Chapter 3,
ongoing structural changes to labour markets as a result of non-monetary
factors, such as globalization and digitalization, have accentuated this
uncertainty. Given the relative flatness of the Phillips curve, inflation is now
less likely to provide a clear signal when employment falls short of its
maximum level. As a result, when it is beneficial to do so, the Bank may
choose to actively seek, and continuously update its estimates of, maximum
sustainable employment.
To seek maximum employment, the Bank may sometimes tighten its
monetary policy stance more gradually than it would have in the past when
inflation is near the 2 percent target and employment is near the Bank’s
current estimate of the maximum sustainable level. Such a policy is often
referred to as probing, and it can allow employment to rise above the Bank’s
current estimate of its maximum sustainable level as long as inflation remains
near the midpoint of the inflation-control range and the Bank does not see
clear evidence of rapidly building inflationary pressures.
68 One reason many central bankseven those with a dual mandatedo not have a numerical target for
employment is because accurately identifying the level of maximum sustainable employment is impossible. This
level is largely determined by non-monetary factors that affect the structure of labour markets and cause
fluctuations in employment. As a result, the level may vary over time in response to changing economic forces.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 69
With probing, inflation might temporarily rise above the 2 percent target if
the level of maximum employment has not increased. This risk is offset by the
value of learning when the current estimate of maximum employment is too
low. Probing will also lower the likelihood of inflation remaining below
2 percent for extended periods.
Patience and probing will leverage the flexibility and credibility of the
framework to help manage uncertainty. The potential benefits of patience and
probing will need to be balanced against the risk that maximum sustainable
employment is lower than thought, which would lead to a larger overshoot in
inflation than projected. This cost-benefit calculation will depend on the
inflation context and economic conditions.
Maintaining well-anchored inflation expectations
Keeping medium-term inflation expectations anchored at 2 percent is
essential to maintaining the effectiveness of monetary policy. Combined with
low and stable inflation, well-anchored medium-term expectations help
provide Canadians with a stable environment in which to make long-term
saving and investment decisions. Moreover, when inflation expectations
remain well anchored, the framework has the flexibility to return inflation to
target over an appropriate time horizon. Since well-anchored inflation
expectations are critical to achieving both price stability and maximum
sustainable employment, the primary objective of monetary policy is to
maintain low, stable inflation over time.
Although patience and probing have distinct aimsto help manage the ELB
constraint and identify the maximum level of employment, respectivelythey
are complementary. Both imply that inflation should sometimes be allowed to
temporarily and modestly overshoot the 2 percent target. By allowing such
overshoots, both practices would help offset the downward bias of inflation
associated with the ELB and keep inflation closer to 2 percent on average.
This, in turn, should help reduce the risk of de-anchoring inflation
expectations downward if ELB episodes become more frequent.
The use of the flexibility provided by the inflation-control range does not
imply that the Bank has adopted so-called makeup strategies that pursue a
period of above-target inflation after a period of below-target inflation. While
patience and probing may result in modest and temporary overshoots of the
inflation target, these overshoots may not happen if the productive capacity
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 70
of the economy is larger than assumed. Thus, this approach to using the
flexibility of the inflation-control range differs from a policy of committing to
systematically pursuing above-target inflation for a prolonged period.
A patient approach of maintaining low rates when there is heightened
uncertainty over the level of maximum sustainable employment can help the
Bank achieve its inflation target; however, this approach poses
implementation challenges. If the Bank were to respond too late to a period
of accelerating inflation in the presence of a flat Phillips curve, the output cost
of reversing an increase in inflation expectations could be substantial. In
addition, if the Bank were to repeatedly respond too late to growing
inflationary pressures, inflation expectations could become de-anchored and
drift upward.
69
As part of its approach, the Bank will develop a dashboard that includes a
range of indicators of labour market performance.
70
The Bank will carefully
monitor, assess and refine these and other indicators of inflationary pressures
over the coming years.
Assessing financial vulnerabilities
The Bank will continue to assess financial system vulnerabilities, recognizing
that a low interest rate environment with high levels of debt can lead to
financial imbalances. A variety of microprudential, macroprudential and
housing policy tools are better suited to address these financial vulnerabilities
than monetary policy is. The recent experience with macroprudential policy in
Canada, particularly in housing finance, suggests that well-designed policy
tools can mitigate financial vulnerabilities and reduce systemic risk in the
financial system (see Chapter 3). The Bank will continue to work with the
Department of Finance Canada and other relevant regulatory agencies to
ensure that Canadian arrangements for financial regulation and supervision
remain fit for purpose.
69 The Bank remains mindful of lessons from history in the conduct of monetary policy, particularly the experience
of the Great Inflation from 1965 to 1982. Economists continue to debate the factors behind the sustained rise
in inflation in the 1970s, but they agree that central bank policy played a key role. This episode clearly
demonstrated that there is no long-run trade-off between lower unemployment rates and higher inflation (e.g.,
Bryan 2013). Another enduring insight is the importance of well-anchored inflation expectations, as shifting
expectations contributed to the Great Inflation and the subsequent cost of lowering inflation (e.g., Solow 1979).
70 Ens et al. (2021) outline a preliminary approach to a range of labour market indicators to help guide monetary
policy.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 71
Nevertheless, the Bank will remain mindful that monetary policy could
exacerbate financial vulnerabilities. Elevated financial vulnerabilities and
possible episodes of financial stress could eventually lead to worse economic
outcomes. This intertemporal trade-off poses a challenge for monetary policy
because it may make it harder to achieve the inflation target in the future.
71
The Bank has made important strides in incorporating issues related to
financial vulnerabilities into its discussion of monetary policy. It will continue
to refine and improve its understanding of these issues in line with the Bank’s
risk management approach to the conduct of monetary policy outlined in the
2016 renewal.
72
This approach aims to more effectively manage the trade-off
between risks to the inflation target now and those in the future.
Building capacity to assess the impact of climate
change
Climate change poses substantial risks to the global and Canadian economies.
While monetary policy cannot directly tackle the threats posed by climate
change, the Bank will take into account the important effects of climate
change on the Canadian economy and financial system and will work with
international and Canadian partners to mitigate climate-related financial risks.
To conduct monetary policy effectively, the Bank must understand the
potential impacts of climate change on the macroeconomy, inflation and jobs.
Climate change is also highly relevant to the Bank’s mandate to foster a stable
and efficient financial system. To address climate change consistent with its
mandate, the Bank will:
advance the development of its modelling tools and conduct further
research to better understand and assess the macroeconomic implications
of climate change
review its operational framework for monetary policy with a view to
including climate change considerations where appropriate
assess the risks that climate change poses by supporting the identification
of risk exposures, promoting best practices in climate risk disclosure and
71 See Beaudry (2020a).
72 See Bank of Canada (2016).
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 72
management for the financial sector, and enabling efficient pricing of
climate-related risks in the market
Enhancing communications
Monetary policy works best when it is well understood and the reasons
behind decisions are clearly explained. Through the years, the Bank has
sought to become more transparent in communicating its goals and
explaining its conduct of monetary policy (Box 10). With these important
changes to the implementation of monetary policy, the Bank will
communicate clearly when and why it is making use of the flexibility of the
1 to 3 percent inflation-control range.
Box 10:
Evolving communications, increased transparency
Over the past 30 years, central banks, including the Bank of Canada, have moved
from communicating very little about their policies and actions to progressively
increasing transparency (Poloz 2018). These efforts have enhanced the credibility and
effectiveness of monetary policy actions by guiding expectations, and they have
fostered greater accountability and public trust in the central bank.
The advent of inflation targeting in 1991 provided a clear objective for monetary
policy and gave the public a straightforward way to measure the performance of
their central bank over time. Since then, the Bank has implemented a series of
communications initiatives to:
demonstrate its accountability
explain its economic projections and policy decisions
provide open access to staff research and data
include insights from businesses, financial markets and consumers in the policy
process
Notable initial measures include:
publishing the Bank’s forecasts for the economy and inflation in the Monetary
Policy Report (MPR)
establishing regional offices to act as the Bank’s representatives with
stakeholders across the country
appearing regularly before parliamentary committees to explain the Bank’s policy
decisions
introducing eight fixed announcement dates for interest rate decisions,
accompanied by a press release explaining the decision
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 73
establishing a formal and regular monetary policy framework renewal process,
with a clear and public research agenda
Over the past three decades,
the number of speeches and
media activities by Governing
Council members has increased
significantly (Chart 11-A). These
speeches provide the public
with greater insight into the
Bank’s thinking on the
economy.
More recently, the Bank
expanded the content of the
opening statements for the
MPR and introduced speeches
presenting an economic
progress report after policy
decisions not accompanied by
an MPR. These changes provide greater insight into Governing Council’s policy
deliberations.
Input from businesses, financial markets and consumers has played a greater role in
the decision-making and communications process through the Business Outlook
Survey, the Senior Loan Officer Survey and, more recently, the Canadian Survey of
Consumer Expectations.
The Bank also now regularly publishes staff research and analysis that feed into the
policy-making and forecasting processes, including staff projections with a time lag.
In addition, where possible, the Bank provides open access to its data and models
(Wilkins 2015).
The Bank has also expanded the range of stakeholders it engages with, putting in
place a dedicated stakeholder relations function and strategy to guide its efforts
(Macklem 2020). Overall, the Bank has sought to better understand the information
needs of its various audiences. Accordingly, it has expanded its digital and social
media presence to offer content accessible to anyone interested in gaining a better
understanding of the economy and the Bank’s role.
When the COVID-19 pandemic struck, the Bank responded with unprecedented
policy actions. The Bank’s communications focused on helping Canadians
understand the new tools the Bank used, such as quantitative easing, and how they
contributed to supporting the economic recovery. The Bank placed a premium on
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
1935 1952 1969 1986 2003 2020
Source: Bank of Canada
Last observation: 2020
Chart 11-A: Bank of Canada public
speeches, 1935 to 2021
Speeches
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 74
further enhancing the relatability of its communications and ensuring maximum
transparency by communicating proactively through multiple channels.
During an ELB episode, the Bank will likely use forward guidance on the
expected path of the policy rate. It will continue to be clear about the
rationale for the forward guidance it provides. In these cases, the anticipated
impact on inflation will be reflected within the Bank’s published forecasts.
A key input for determining the appropriate path for monetary policy is the
Bank’s assessment of the output gap. Employment is the most important
element in this assessment, but its importance has not been emphasized
consistently in past communications. Moving forward, the Bank will
systematically report to Canadians on the role played by labour market
outcomes in the assessment of the output gap and forecasts of inflation. This
will include more extensive reporting on a broad set of labour market
indicators and how they factor into its monetary policy decisions.
By helping to achieve maximum sustainable employment, monetary policy
contributes to a more inclusive economy that provides opportunities for
Canadians to participate in the labour market. However, monetary policy is a
broad macroeconomic instrument that cannot target specific segments of the
economy. As a result, monetary policy can play only a supporting role in
promoting better and more inclusive employment outcomes.
Providing increased clarity on the conduct of monetary policy helps build on
the Bank’s past success in achieving low and stable inflation and contributing
to overall macroeconomic stability. Leveraging the flexibility of the framework
addresses important structural changes in Canada’s economy and is intended
to maximize the shared benefits that monetary policy can deliver for
Canadians. The clarity and continuity of the renewed monetary policy
framework will continue to support the Bank’s primary objective of
maintaining low, stable inflation over time.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 75
References
Acharya, S., E. Challe and K. Dogra. 2021. “Optimal Monetary Policy According
to HANK.” Bank of Canada Staff Working Paper No. 2021-55.
Acharya, S. and K. Dogra. 2020. “Understanding HANK: Insights from a Prank.”
Econometrica 88 (3): 11131158.
Adrian, T., N. Boyarchenko and D. Giannone. 2019. Vulnerable
Growth.” American Economic Review 109 (4): 12631289.
Ahnert, T., J. Bengui and B. Peterson. Forthcoming. Complementarities
Between Monetary and Macroprudential Policies: A Literature Review.“
Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper.
Albouy, D., A. Chernoff, C. Lutz and C. Warman. 2019. Local Labor Markets in
Canada and the United States.Journal of Labor Economics 37 (S2):
S533–S594.
Amano, R., S. Gnocchi, S. Leduc and J. Wagner. 2020. “Average Is Good
Enough: Average-Inflation Targeting and the ELB.” Bank of Canada Staff
Working Paper No. 2020-31.
Ambler, S. 2020. “Nominal GDP Level Targeting.” Paper prepared for McGill
University Max Bell School Monetary Policy Online Conference,
“Choosing the Right Target: Real Options for the Bank of Canada’s
Mandate Renewal,” September 2225.
Arora, R., S. Gungor, K. McRae and J. Witmer. 2020. “Announcing the Bankers’
Acceptance Purchase Facility: A COVID‑19 Event Study.” Bank of
Canada Staff Analytical Note No. 2020-23.
Arora, R., S. Gungor, J. Nesrallah, G. Ouellet Leblanc and J. Witmer. 2021. “The
Impact of the Bank of Canada’s Government Bond Purchase Program.
Bank of Canada Staff Analytical Note No. 2021-23.
Autor, D., D. Cho, L. D. Crane, M. Goldar, B. Lutz, J. Montes, W. B. Peterman,
D. Ratner, D. Villar and A. Yildirmaz. 2020. “An Evaluation of the
Paycheck Protection Program Using Administrative Payroll Microdata.”
Mimeo.
Ball, L. M. and S. Mazumder. 2011.Inflation Dynamics and the Great
Recession.Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Spring): 337405.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 76
Bank of Canada. 2011. Renewal of the Inflation-Control Target: Background
Information—November 2011.
Bank of Canada. 2015. Framework for Conducting Monetary Policy at Low
Interest Rates.
Bank of Canada. 2016. Renewal of the Inflation-Control Target: Background
Information–October 2016.
Bank of Canada. 2018.Box 1: Mortgage interest rate stress tests.” Financial
System Review (June): 5.
Bank of Canada. 2021a. Box 5: Diverging measures of core inflation under
COVID-19.” Monetary Policy Report (April): 1819.
Bank of Canada. 2021b. Toward 2021: Consultations with Canadians.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2021. Early Lessons from the
COVID-19 Pandemic on the Basel Reforms.
Barnett, R., S. Kozicki and C. Petrinec. 2009. Parsing Shocks: Real-Time
Revisions to Gap and Growth Projections for Canada.” Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Review (July/August) 91 (4): 247266.
Beaudry, P. 2020a. “Monetary Policy and Financial Vulnerabilities.” Remarks at
Université Laval, Québec, Quebec, January 30.
Beaudry, P. 2020b. “Our Quantitative Easing Operations: Looking Under the
Hood.” Speech to the Greater Moncton Chamber of Commerce, the
Fredericton Chamber of Commerce and the Saint John Region
Chamber of Commerce, delivered virtually, December 10.
Beaudry, P. and M. Doyle. 2000. What Happened to the Phillips Curve in the
1990s in Canada?In Price Stability and the Long-Run Target for
Monetary Policy, 5197. Proceedings of a seminar held by the Bank of
Canada (June).
Blit, J. 2020.Automation and Reallocation: Will COVID-19 Usher in the Future
of Work? Canadian Public Policy, Special Issue on COVID-19, 46 (S2):
S192202.
Boire, F.-M., T. Duprey and A. Ueberfeldt. 2021. “Shaping the Future: Policy
Shocks and the GDP Growth Distribution.” Bank of Canada Staff
Working Paper No. 2021-24.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 77
Brouillette, D., G. Faucher, M. Kuncl, A. McWhirter and Y. Park. 2021. Potential
Output and the Neutral Rate in Canada: 2021 Update.” Bank of Canada
Staff Analytical Note No. 2021-6.
Brouillette, D., M.-N. Robitaille, L. Savoie-Chabot, P. St-Amant, B. Gueye and E.
Nelson. 2019. The Trend Unemployment Rate in Canada: Searching for
the Unobservable.” Bank of Canada Staff Working Paper No. 2019-13.
Brunnermeier, M. K. and Y. Koby. 2018. The Reversal Interest Rate.” National
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 25406.
Bryan, M. 2013. The Great Inflation: 19651982.” Federal Reserve History
(November 22).
Bullard, J. and R. DiCecio. 2019. “Optimal Monetary Policy for the Masses.”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper No. 2019-009.
Cacciatore, M., D. Matveev and R. Sekkel. Forthcoming. “Uncertainty and
Monetary Policy Experimentation: Empirical Challenges and Insights
from the Academic Literature.” Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper.
Carter, T. J. and R. Mendes. Forthcoming.Searching for the Maximum
Sustainable Level of Output in a Simple New Keynesian Model.” Bank of
Canada Staff Discussion Paper.
Carter, T. J., R. Mendes and L. L. Schembri. 2018. Credibility, Flexibility and
Renewal: The Evolution of Inflation Targeting in Canada.In Central
Bank Frameworks: Evolution or Revolution?, edited by J. Simon and
M. Sutton, 2552. Proceedings of Reserve Bank of Australia Annual
Conference.
Champagne, J., G. Poulin-Bellisle and R. Sekkel. 2018. “The Real-Time
Properties of the Bank of Canada's Staff Output Gap Estimates.” Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking 50 (6): 11671188.
Chetty, R., J. N. Friedman, N. Hendren, M. Stepner and The Opportunity
Insights Team. 2020. “The Economic Impacts of COVID-19: Evidence
from a New Public Database Built Using Private Sector Data.” National
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 27431.
Chu, V. and Y. Zhang. Forthcoming. “Harnessing the Benefit of Extraordinary
Forward Guidance.” Bank of Canada Staff Analytical Note.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 78
Cloyne, J., C. Ferreira and P. Surico. 2020. “Monetary Policy when Households
Have Debt: New Evidence on the Transmission Mechanism.Review of
Economic Studies 87 (1): 102129.
Corrigan, P., H. Desgagnes, J. Dorich, V. Lepetyuk, W. Miyamoto and Y. Zhang.
2021. ToTEM III: The Bank of Canada's Main DSGE Model for Projection
and Policy Analysis.” Bank of Canada Technical Report No. 119.
De Resende, C., R. Lalonde and S. Snudden. 2010.The Power of Many:
Assessing the Economic Impact of the Global Fiscal Stimulus.” Bank of
Canada Staff Discussion Paper No. 2010-1.
Del Negro, M., D. Giannone, M. P. Giannoni and A. Tambalotti. 2019. Global
Trends in Interest Rates.” Journal of International Economics 118 (C):
248262.
Del Negro, M., M. Lenza, G. E. Primiceri and A. Tambalotti. 2020.What’s Up
with the Phillips Curve?Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Spring):
301357.
Djeutem, E., A. Reza and Y. Zhang. Forthcoming. “Household Heterogeneity
and the Performance of Monetary Policy Frameworks.” Bank of Canada
Staff Working Paper.
Dong, W., G. R. Dunbar, C. Friedrich, D. Matveev, R. Priftis and L. Shao. 2021.
Complementarities Between Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy
Literature Review.” Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper No. 2021-4.
Dorich, J., R. Mendes and Y. Zhang 2021. “The Bank of Canada’s ”Horse Race”
of Alternative Monetary Policy Frameworks: Some Interim Results from
Model Simulations.” Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper
No. 2021-13.
Duprey, T., T. Grieder and D. Hogg. 2017. “Recent Evolution of Canada’s
Credit-to-GDP Gap: Measurement and Interpretation.” Bank of Canada
Staff Analytical Note No. 2017-25.
Duprey, T. and A. Ueberfeldt. 2020. “Managing GDP Tail Risk.” Bank of Canada
Staff Working Paper No. 2020-3.
Ens, E., L. Savoie-Chabot, K. See and S. L. Wee. 2021. “Assessing Labour
Market Slack for Monetary Policy.Bank of Canada Staff Discussion
Paper No. 2021-15.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 79
Feunou, B. and J.-S. Fontaine. Forthcoming.Secular Economic Changes and
Bond Yields." Review of Economics and Statistics.
Fitzgerald, T. J., C. Jones, M. Kulish and J. P. Nicolini. 2020.Is There a Stable
Relationship Between Unemployment and Future Inflation?Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Working Paper No. 713.
Fontaine, J.-S., H. Ford and A. Walton. 2020. “COVID-19 and Bond Market
Liquidity: Alert, Isolation and Recovery.” Bank of Canada Staff Analytical
Note No. 2020-14.
Gabaix, X. 2020. “A Behavioral New Keynesian Model.” American Economic
Review 110 (8): 22712327.
Gordon, R. J. 2011. The History of the Phillips Curve: Consensus and
Bifurcation.” Economica 78 (309): 1050.
Gosselin, M.-A. and M. Khan. 2015. A Survey of Consumer Expectations for
Canada.” Bank of Canada Review (Autumn): 1423.
Gravelle, T. 2021a. Market Stress Relief: The Role of the Bank of Canada’s
Balance Sheet.” Speech to the CFA Society Toronto, delivered virtually,
March 23.
Gravelle, T. 2021b. Economic Progress Report: A Recovery Unlike Any Other.”
Speech to the Surrey Board of Trade, Surrey, British Columbia, delivered
virtually, December 9.
Hazell, J., J. Herreño, E. Nakamura and J. Steinsson. 2020.The Slope of the
Phillips Curve: Evidence from US States.” National Bureau of Economic
Research Working Paper No. 28005.
Hsieh, C.-T., E. Hurst, C. I. Jones and P. J. Klenow. 2019. “The Allocation of
Talent and U.S. Economic Growth.” Econometrica 87 (5): 14391474.
International Monetary Fund. 2019. Canada: Financial Sector Assessment
Program Technical NoteSystemic Risk Oversight and Macroprudential
Policy.” IMF Staff Country Report No. 2020/019.
Jaimovich, N. and H. E. Siu. 2020. Job Polarization and Jobless Recoveries.
Review of Economics and Statistics 102 (1): 129147.
Jeon, S.-H., H. Liu and Y. Ostrovsky. 2019. “Measuring the Gig Economy in
Canada Using Administrative Data.” Statistics Canada Analytical Studies
Branch Research Paper Series 11F0019M No. 437.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 80
Johnson, G., S. Kozicki, R. Priftis, L. Suchanek, J. Witmer and J. Yang. 2020.
Implementation and Effectiveness of Extended Monetary Policy Tools:
Lessons from the Literature.” Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper No.
2020-16.
Kaplan, G., B. Moll and G. L. Violante. 2018. “Monetary Policy According to
HANK.American Economic Review 108 (3): 697743.
Kartashova, K. and X. Zhou. 2020. “How Do Mortgage Rate Resets Affect
Consumer Spending and Debt Repayment? Evidence from Canadian
Consumers.” Bank of Canada Staff Working Paper No. 2020-18.
Keshishbanoosy, R., F. Tarkhani, A. Xu, C. Yélou, P. Sabourin and
O. Kostyshyna. Forthcoming. “Consumer Price Index Inflation and
Inflation Perceptions in Canada: Can Measurement Approaches or
Behavioural Factors Explain the Gap?” Statistics Canada Prices Analytical
Series 62F0014M.
Khan, M., L. Morel and P. Sabourin. 2015. “A Comprehensive Evaluation of
Measures of Core Inflation for Canada.” Bank of Canada Staff
Discussion Paper No. 2015-12.
Kichian, M. 2001.On the Nature and the Stability of the Canadian Phillips
Curve.” Bank of Canada Staff Working Paper No. 2001-4.
Kostyshyna, O. and E. Lalé. 2019.On the Evolution of Multiple Jobholding in
Canada.” Bank of Canada Staff Working Paper No. 2019-49.
Kostyshyna, O. and C. Luu. 2019. “The Size and Characteristics of Informal
(‘Gig) Work in Canada.” Bank of Canada Staff Analytical Note No.
2019-6.
Kostyshyna, O. and L. Petersen. Forthcoming. “Communicating Central Bank
Statistics and Uncertainty: Information Experiment.Bank of Canada
Staff Working Paper.
Kostyshyna, O., L. Petersen and J. Yang. Forthcoming. “A Horse Race of
Monetary Policy Regimes: An Experimental Investigation.” Bank of
Canada Staff Working Paper.
Kozicki, S. and J. Vardy. 2017. “Communicating Uncertainty in Monetary
Policy.” Bank of Canada Discussion Paper No. 2017-14.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 81
Kroft, K., F. Lange, M. J. Notowidigdo and M. Tudball. 2019. Long Time Out:
Unemployment and Joblessness in Canada and the United States.”
Journal of Labor Economics 37 (S2): S355–S397.
Kryvtsov, O. and J. C. MacGee. 2020. “Has the Inflation Process Changed?
Selective Review of Recent Research on Inflation Dynamics.” Bank of
Canada Staff Discussion Paper No. 2020-11.
Kuncl, M. 2016. “Assessment of the Effects of Macroprudential Tightening in
Canada.” Bank of Canada Staff Analytical Note No. 2016-12.
Landry, A. and R. Sekkel. Forthcoming.Has the Canadian Phillips Curve
Flattened? Evidence from Vector Autoregressions.” Bank of Canada
Staff Analytical Note.
Lao, H. and C. Steyn. 2019.A Comprehensive Evaluation of Measures of Core
Inflation in Canada: An Update.” Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper
No. 2019-9.
Laubach, T. and J. C. Williams. 2003. Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest.
Review of Economics and Statistics 85 (4): 10631070.
MacGee, J. C., T. M. Pugh and K. See. 2021. “The Heterogeneous Effects of
COVID-19 on Canadian Household Consumption, Debt and Savings.”
Canadian Journal of Economics 54 (Special issue: the COVID-19
pandemic).
MacKay, A. and R. Reis. 2016. “The Role of Automatic Stabilizers in the U.S.
Business Cycle.” Econometrica 84 (1): 141194.
Macklem, T. 2012. “Promoting Growth, Mitigating Cycles and Inequality: The
Role of Price and Financial Stability.” Speech to the BrazilCanada
Chamber of Commerce, São Paulo, Brazil, March 12.
Macklem, T. 2020. “The Imperative for Public Engagement.” Speech to the
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Jackson Hole Symposium, Jackson
Hole, Wyoming, delivered virtually August 27.
Macklem, T. 2021. “The Benefits of an Inclusive Economy.” Speech to the
universities of Atlantic Canada, delivered virtually, May 13.
Meh, C. A. and S. S. Poloz. 2018. “Investing in Monetary Policy Sovereignty:
Ideas from the Periphery.” In Monetary Policy Spillovers in a Financially
Integrated World, 6680. Proceedings of the Joint Danmarks
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 82
Nationalbank–Bank for International Settlements conference,
September 78. Copenhagen: Danmarks Nationalbank.
Mendes, R. and S. Murchison. 2014. “Should Forward Guidance Be Backward-
Looking?Bank of Canada Review (Autumn): 1222.
Miyamoto, W., T. L. Nguyen and D. Sergeyev. 2018. “Government Spending
Multipliers Under the Zero Lower Bound: Evidence from Japan.”
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 10 (3): 247277.
Morissette, R. 2021. Chapter 2: Youth Employment in Canada.In Portrait of
Youth in Canada: Data Report. Statistics Canada (July 26).
Orphanides, A. and S. van Norden. 2002. “The Unreliability of Output-Gap
Estimates in Real Time.” Review of Economics and Statistics 84 (4): 569
583.
Ostry, D., J. Alvarez, R. A. Espinoza and C. Papageorgiou. 2018. “Economic
Gains from Gender Inclusion: New Mechanisms, New Evidence.”
International Monetary Fund Staff Discussion Note No. 18/06.
Petit, G. and L. M. Tedds. 2020. “The Effect of Differences in Treatment of the
Canada Emergency Response Benefit Across Provincial and Territorial
Income Assistance Programs.” Canadian Public Policy 46 (S1): S29S43.
Poloz, S. S. 2018. Let Me Be Clear: From Transparency to Trust and
Understanding.” Speech to the Greater Victoria Chamber of Commerce,
Victoria, British Columbia, June 27.
Poloz, S. S. 2020. Monetary Policy in Unknowable Times.” Eric J. Hanson
Memorial Lecture, University of Alberta, Edmonton, Alberta, May 25.
Ramey, V. A. and S. Zubairy. 2018. “Government Spending Multipliers in Good
Times and in Bad: Evidence from US Historical Data.Journal of Political
Economy 126 (2): 850901.
Romer, C. D. 2021. “The Fiscal Policy Response to the Pandemic.Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity Conference Draft (Spring).
Rose, A. K. 2020. “IPhones, iCrises and iTargets: Inflation Targeting Is
Eradicating International Financial Crises in the iPhone Era.” Centre for
Economic Policy Research Policy Insight No. 100.
Rose, D. 1988.The NAIRU in Canada: Concepts, Determinants and
Estimates.” Bank of Canada Technical Report No. 50.
Monetary Policy Framework Renewal | 2021 | Page 83
Sabourin, P. and P. Duguay. 2015.Measuring Durable Goods and Housing
Prices in the CPI: An Empirical Assessment.” Bank of Canada Review
(Autumn): 2438.
Schroth, J. 2021. “Optimal Monetary and Macroprudential Policies.” Bank of
Canada Staff Working Paper No. 2021-21.
Setterfield, M. A., D. V. Gordon and L. O. Osberg. 1992. “Searching for a Will o'
the Wisp: An Empirical Study of the NAIRU in Canada. European
Economic Review 36 (1): 119136.
Sheedy, K. D. 2014.Debt and Incomplete Financial Markets: A Case for
Nominal GDP Targeting.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
(Spring): 301361.
Solow, R. M. 1979. “What We Know and Dont Know about Inflation.”
Technology Review 81 (3): 30–46.
Staiger, D., J. H. Stock and M. W. Watson. 1997.The NAIRU, Unemployment
and Monetary Policy.Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (1): 3349.
Stella, P. 1997. “Do Central Banks Need Capital?” International Monetary Fund
Working Paper 97/83. July.
Swarbrick, J. and Y. Zhang. Forthcoming. “A Horse Race of Monetary Policy
Strategies for Canada.” Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper.
Wagner, J., T. Schlanger and Y. Zhang. Forthcoming. “A Horse Race of
Alternative Monetary Policy Regimes Under Bounded Rationality.” Bank
of Canada Staff Discussion Paper.
Wilkins, C. A. 2015. “Innovation, Central-Bank Style.” Speech to the Rotman
School of Management and Munk School of Global Affairs, Toronto,
Ontario, November 13.
Witmer, J. and J. Yang. 2016.Estimating Canada’s Effective Lower Bound.”
Bank of Canada Review (Spring): 314.
Woodford, M. 2003. Interest and Prices: Foundation of a Theory of Monetary
Policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Yagan, D. 2019. Employment Hysteresis from the Great Recession.Journal of
Political Economy 127 (5): 25052558.
Zhang, Y., L. Suchanek, J. Swarbrick, J. Wagner and T. Schlanger. 2021.
Sequencing Extended Monetary Policies at the Effective Lower Bound.
Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper No. 2021-10.