Can Displaced Labor Be Retrained? Evidence from
Quasi-Random Assignment to Trade Adjustment Assistance
Benjamin G. Hyman
University of Chicago
This Draft: November 20, 2018
Click Here for Latest Version
Abstract
The extent to which workers adjust to labor market disruptions in light of increasing
pressure from trade and automation commands widespread concern. Yet little is known
about efforts that deliberately target the adjustment process. This project studies 20 years
of worker-level earnings and re-employment responses to Trade Adjustment Assistance
(TAA)—a large social insurance program that couples retraining incentives with extended
unemployment insurance (UI) for displaced workers. I estimate causal effects from the
quasi-random assignment of TAA cases to investigators of varying approval leniencies.
Using employer-employee matched Census data on 300,000 workers, I find TAA-approved
workers have $50,000 greater cumulative earnings ten years out—driven by both higher
incomes and greater labor force participation. Yet annual returns fully depreciate over the
same period. In the most disrupted regions, workers are more likely to switch industries
and move to labor markets with better opportunities in response to TAA. Combined with
evidence that sustained returns are delivered by training rather than UI transfers, the results
imply a potentially important role for human capital in overcoming adjustment frictions.
I am deeply indebted to Gilles Duranton, Fernando Ferreira, Jessie Handbury, Ann Harrison, and Ben Keys for extensive
advising on this project. I thank David Atkin, David Autor, Anna Cororaton, Matt Davis, Anthony DeFusco, Deeksha Gupta,
Erik Hurst, Bob Inman, Illenin Kondo, Jake Krimmel, Ben Lockwood, Ioana Marinescu, Magne Mogstad, Ryan Monarch, Matt
Notowidigdo, Justin Pierce, Todd Sinai, Boris Vabson, Chris Walters, Maisy Wong, and seminar participants at the IADB,
FRBNY, Johns Hopkins SAIS, NBER Trade and Labor Markets, NBER Labor Studies, UC-Berkeley, UChicago, UChicago-Booth,
USC-Price, and UT-Austin McCombs for helpful comments. I am particularly grateful to Ryan Monarch, Jooyoun Park, and
Jagadeesh Sivadasan for sharing their firm-matching code, and Brian Kovak for additional take-up data. I acknowledge
generous financial support from the Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation Dissertation Fellowship, and the Wharton Mack
Institute for Innovation. This research uses data from the Census Bureau’s Longitudinal Employer Household Dynamics
Program, which was partially supported by National Science Foundation Grants: SES-9978093, SES-0339191 and ITR-0427889;
National Institute on Aging Grant AG018854; and grants from the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation. Support for this research at
the Suitland RDC from NSF (ITR-0426889) is also gratefully acknowledged. All results have been reviewed to ensure that no
confidential information is disclosed. Research results and conclusions expressed are those of the author and do not reflect the
views of the Census Bureau. All errors are my own. Email: [email protected].
1 Introduction
Between 2000 and 2016, the US shed approximately 6 million manufacturing jobs, resulting in the lowest
level of manufacturing employment since the onset of World War II (BLS, 2017).
1
Strikingly, this decline
contrasted with record revenue growth in both manufacturing and non-manufacturing industries over
the same period (see Figure 1). In light of increasing pressure from trade and automation, are today’s
workers able to adjust to labor market disruptions as they have in the past, or do frictions in the
adjustment process imply a greater role for policy in targeting those displaced?
While trade economists have shown that removing import barriers can increase growth and
consumer welfare through specialization, lower goods prices, and higher variety,
2
less attention had
been given to adverse consequences for labor because imports from low-wage countries were relatively
inconsequential until the 1990s (Autor et al., 2016). Not robustly detected in the data, the implication was
that growing industries could indeed absorb and offset declining earnings among displaced workers
with little friction.
3
More recently however, influential papers in empirical trade and labor economics
have documented that displaced workers may remain persistently underemployed and underpaid (with
respect to prior earnings) years beyond their initial job separation (Bartik A., 2017; Lachowksa et al., 2017;
Pierce and Schott, 2016; Flaaen et al., 2016; Autor et al., 2014, 2013; Autor and Dorn, 2013; Harrison and
McMillan, 2011).
4
The unusual speed and persistence of these structural changes has generated equal
concern about how future generations will adapt to work in a rapidly automating economy.
5
Despite widespread attention, remarkably little is know about whether the US’s largest and longest
standing incentive program for retraining displaced workers—the Department of Labor’s 1974 Trade
Adjustment Assistance (TAA) program—is a necessary, effective, or efficient means to accelerate
adjustment. This main goal of this paper is to provide large-sample empirical estimates of the causal
effects of TAA on three labor market outcomes: earnings, employment, and mobility. Credible parameter
estimates of these effects have historically been complicated by two factors: (1) A lack of detailed
worker-level data to track TAA participants before and after displacement events across employers; (2)
1
Pierce and Schott (2016) highlight that the recent manufacturing decline contrasts with a stable employment trend which
had varied around 18 million jobs from 1965 until the accession of China to the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001.
2
Recent work by Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal (2016) further suggests low-income workers have the most to gain from trade,
as they bear a disproportionate incidence of lower consumer prices due to a higher propensity to consume tradable goods.
3
Ricardian trade models conventionally assume displaced workers either adjust instantaneously to newly expanding
sectors (i.e. labor is perfectly mobile), or are compensated by redistributive transfers that preserve trade’s Pareto-improving
qualities. The latter relies on the notion of “Kaldor-Hicks Efficiency” (Kaldor, 1939; Hicks, 1939), which relaxes Pareto
assumptions such that efficient trade need only require that losing production factors be hypothetically compensatable by
winning factors. This allows agnosticism as to the effectiveness of the redistribution itself—the subject of the current paper.
4
Feenstra et al. (2017) and Feenstra and Sasahara (2017) find that manufacturing job losses are offset by service job growth,
however these papers do not address distributional consequences which can persist despite aggregate gains.
5
For example, 1.3 million truck drivers are expected to have to compete with the emergence of self-driving vehicle
technology by 2026 (CEA, 2016).
1
Confounding factors correlated with qualifying for TAA, particularly pre-determined skills and trends
associated with tradable-good production and training take-up—selection biases which preclude reliable
estimates of the program’s effects. In this paper, I employ a quasi-experimental research design that
builds on the rapidly maturing “examiner literature to circumvent these endogeneity concerns in a
two-stage least squares (2SLS) setting.
6
I first assemble a new dataset combining restricted-use administrative data from the US Census
Bureau’s Longitudinal Employer-Household Dynamics (LEHD) program with the universe of TAA
winning and losing petitions (applications) attained through FOIA requests at the US Department of
Labor (USDOL). This merger allows me to track approximately 300,000 displaced workers as they move
in and out of unemployment status and across employers of diverse industries and regions, both before
and after their initial job separation. Critically, the USDOL assigns TAA petitions to case investigators
tasked with determining whether applicants were laid off by companies whose decline in production
(sales) was due to increased imports or offshoring—an adjudication of the firm’s trade exposure or
“tradability” status. This institutional feature of TAA effectively assigns two otherwise identical worker
cohorts displaced from the same industry, different approval probabilities based on whether their case
is directed to a more lenient versus strict investigator. If assigned to more lenient investigators, displaced
workers have a higher likelihood of receiving TAA benefits, amounting on average to $10,000/year for
two years of training and $15,000/year of extended unemployment insurance (UI) while training.
7
I find evidence of large initial returns to TAA. Workers inferred to take up benefits forego roughly
$10,000 in income while training, yet ten years later have approximately $50,000 higher cumulative
earnings relative to all-else-equal workers that do not retrain. I estimate that 33% of these returns
are driven by higher wages—a sizable share which suggests that TAA-trained workers are not only
compensated through greater labor force participation or higher priority in job queues. Rather, TAA
workers also appear to be paid a premium for their newly acquired human capital. But these large
relative gains also decay over time, such that annual incomes among TAA and non-TAA workers fully
converge after ten years. In conjunction with two additional pieces of evidence—that TAA has no effect
on formal education, and diminishing returns are restricted to states with low training durations—I
attribute this depreciation to short-run demanded skills becoming obsolete (consistent with rapid
6
Recent examples of such examiner designs include Dobbie and Song (2015), who use the random assignment of
bankruptcy judges to establish the causal effects of consumer bankruptcy insurance on debtor outcomes; Autor et al. (2015),
who study the welfare impact of disability benefits in Norway; and Mueller-Smith (2015), who studies the impacts of
incarceration. The original idea to exploit judge randomization as a causal design can be attributed to Kling (2006), and the
first quasi-experimental examiner design can be attributed to Doyle (2008)
7
While this design is well-equipped to estimate an important adjustment parameter with respect to training, the TAA
treatment effect (estimated here using an intent-to-treat framework) should be thought of as just one input into a richer trade
model characterizing the full efficiency and distributional consequences of trade liberalization.
2
skill-biased technological change or an overall declining labor share).
8
Indeed, 62% of TAA training
programs confer vocational degrees with shorter program lengths than typical community college or
4-year college degrees which have been shown to have durable earnings returns (Card (2001); Kane and
Rouse (1995)).
While these results provide strong evidence that overall earnings returns to TAA are largely positive,
government intervention in the adjustment process is only warranted economically in the presence of
market failures or if redistribution is socially desirable.
9
While human capital theory suggests that wage
differentials across occupations should provide ample incentives for workers and firms to privately
undertake skill upgrading (Becker, 1964), laid off machine operators in Detroit’s automobile sector
may face a variety of frictions that prevent them from acquiring productive employment in expanding
sectors such as robotics occupations in Pittsburgh’s burgeoning 3D-printing industry. Among several
possible barriers to adjustment, these frictions may be spatial or industrial—high mobility costs across
labor markets and industries stagnate worker wages in trade-afflicted labor markets (Bartik A., 2017;
Yagan, 2014; Kline and Moretti, 2013; Blanchard and Katz, 1992); informational—search costs result
in job mismatch after displacement (Moretensen and Pissarides, 1994); financial—liquidity constraints
preclude the necessary investments in retraining and education required for work in the modern
economy (Lochner and Monge-Naranjo, 2011); or behavioral—workers may be “present-biased” or make
forecasting errors about the future viability of their local industries (Augenblick et al., 2015).
To unpack which frictions underlie the main effects (if any), I conduct a variety of empirical tests
exploiting the rich heterogeneity of the administrative data to identify potential mechanisms. I find
strongest support for spatial and industrial adjustment frictions. Merging county-level Bureau of Labor
Statistics (BLS) unemployment rate data to the LEHD panel, I define “high” and “low” shock severity
regions based on whether the county in which a TAA-qualified worker was displaced was above or
below median unemployment in their quarter of separation. I find that workers in highly disrupted
regions are more likely to switch both industries and commuting zones (a now widely used geographic
measure of local labor markets) in response to training. Workers are approximately 20 percentage points
more likely to move commuting zones and 28 percentage points more likely to switch industries (at the
2-digit North American Industrial Classification System (NAICS) level), with respect to the location and
industry of their pre-layoff employer. Lastly, I find no evidence that TAA subsidies lead to deferred job
search, which suggests that effects are more likely due to the training itself and an expansion of potential
firm matches outside of their trade-shocked region, rather than relieving liquidity or search constraints.
8
For a discussion of the potential determinants of the declining labor share in the United States, see Autor et al. (2017).
9
There are arguably other less distortive ways to achieve the latter redistributive goal. See for example recent work by Lyon
and Waugh (2017), who consider optimal progressive taxation schemes to redistribute the gains from trade.
3
While the paper’s identification strategy provides robust evidence of positive earnings returns and
higher mobility associated with TAA, this does not inform us about the cost-effectiveness of the program.
Toward this second end, I compare the ten year stream of estimated TAA differential earnings returns as
benefits, with average TAA expenditures on training, extended UI, and foregone earnings while training,
as costs. I estimate an internal rate of return (IRR) to TAA of between 0.0% and 9.1%, which I interpret
as a lower bound for two reasons. First, earnings returns are calculated from an intent-to-treat (ITT)
estimator which likely understates benefits due to imperfect compliance with the treatment (i.e. partial
take-up of TAA attenuates earnings estimates toward zero and understate the treatment-on-treated
(TOT) effect of interest). Second, TAA may induce worker substitution away from other costly social
insurance programs such as disability insurance (DI), which would further understate program costs.
10
One important caveat however, is that positive earnings returns are estimated from a local average
treatment effect (LATE) that does not capture the fact that firms may be incentivized to lay off additional
workers after learning of their TAA eligibility status. Nevertheless, back-of-the-envelope calculations
show that these are unlikely to outweigh potentially much larger downward pressures.
Overall, this paper provides new quasi-experimental evidence that earnings returns from
trade-adjustment targeting via retraining may be larger and more effective than previously thought.
More work is needed however, to fully understand the extent to which such targeting alleviates
aggregate worker adjustment barriers, and to decompose the relative roles of training and UI in its
success. Despite some noteworthy inefficiencies, TAA may serve as an important tag for redistributing
the growth from trade. However, whether these results can be extrapolated to trade and automation
pressures faced by future workers remains an open question.
1.1 Related Literature
While this paper is one of the first to empirically estimate the effects of TAA on worker outcomes,
the study builds on a long history of scholarship in labor economics, trade, and public economics.
Particularly, this analysis is positioned at the intersection of three literatures: (1) The impact of worker
displacement and trade on inequality; (2) The effects of job training on earnings and human capital
accumulation; (3) The role of local labor market and occupational mobility frictions in earnings growth.
Starting with displacement and inequality, this paper most directly follows the work of Autor et
al. (2016), who study long run earnings adjustment patterns of workers exposed to Chinese import
competition using administrative Social Security Administration (SSA) data. The authors find long-run
negative effects from trade, and show that trade-affected workers take up disability insurance (DI)
10
Autor et al. (2014) find that DI is in fact the predominant margin through which workers adjust to trade shocks.
4
rather than trade adjustment assistance to insure themselves against these shocks.
11
Recently, other
scholars have also studied displacement and inequality through the lenses of trade (Pierce and Schott,
2016; Ebenstein et al., 2014; Autor et al., 2013; Amiti and Davis, 2011; Harrison and McMillan, 2011;
Kletzer, 2004), technology and automation (Autor et al., 2013; Acemoglu and Autor, 2011; Goldin and
Katz, 2009), business cycle fluctuations (Lachowksa et al. (2017), Von Wachter et al. (2009)), and reasons
for separation (Flaaen et al., 2016). One additional catalyst for renewed interest in this topic has been
greater availability of administrative datasets which facilitate more precise estimates of heterogeneous
responses to different types of separation events.
Work on displacement has also been linked to a longer tradition of scholarship on job training, which
has been the source of several methodological advancements in labor economics and debate surrounding
the econometrics of program evaluation. Early literature focused on either model-based econometric
selection correction methods (Heckman, 1976) or difference-in-differences estimators (Ashenfelter
(1978)) to address a number of endogeneity concerns, and found little to no effects of job training on
worker outcomes. Ashenfelter and Card (1985) however, showed that difference-in-differences estimates
were sensitive to the control groups used, while LaLonde (1986) demonstrated that experimental results
did not match non-randomized econometric studies. This was followed by rapid advancement in the
development of matching estimators and propensity score methods (Heckman et al., 1996, 1997), and
continued debate over how to resolve the critique of nonexperimental approaches to estimation.
12
In their 1999 handbook chapter, Heckman, LaLonde, and Smith (1999) bridge the debate by calling for
better data and experimental evidence when possible. Subsequently, in a meta-analysis of 97 job training
program evaluations from 1995 to 2007 that more frequently employ experimental variation and higher
quality data, Card et al. (2010) follow up on prior estimates with a similarly titled handbook chapter, and
conclude that ”...training programmes are associated with positive medium-term impacts, although in
the short term they often appear ineffective.” When converted to standardized effect sizes, this paper’s
employment results fall near the middle of those effect sizes classified as “significantly positive” in the
Card et al. (2010) study: 0.25 (β=0.1/sd=0.4), compared to the Card et al. (2010) median of 0.21.
While TAA is a sizable training program, there is a surprising dearth of evidence on its empirical
effects on workers.
13
One notable exception is a recent study by Mathematica Policy Research authors
11
One can compare these persistent adverse effects form import competition to the relative returns to retraining through
TAA. Importantly however, Autor et al. (2016) consider the joint effect on workers who may see reduced earnings or hours on
the intensive margin, as well as workers who are displaced (the unit of analysis in this paper). These sample differences thus
present important caveats when making direct estimate comparisons.
12
Dehejia and Wahba (1999) first indicated that LaLonde’s critique could be addressed using propensity score methods, but
later work by Smith and Todd (2001) showed the limitations of this approach.
13
Notable exceptions include Feenstra and Lewis (1994), who provide a strong theoretical foundation for considering the role
of adjustment assistance in the context of imperfect mobility. Monarch et al. (2017) and Kondo (2013) also use TAA-approved
plants as a lever to study the effects of offshoring on firms and displacement multipliers respectively.
5
Schochet et al. (2012), who evaluate the effects of TAA by comparing program enrollees with a
propensity-score matched sample of UI claimants that do not take up TAA. The authors find a mostly
negative result, concluding that “...impacts of TAA on engagement in any productive activity were
small.” However, they are also very careful to note two important caveats in interpreting their effects.
First, the sample frame used in their study included manufacturing workers who were laid off just before
a large economic downturn—sampled between 2005 to 2006. Since TAA trainees enroll for up to 2 to 3
years and the study only tracked workers for 4 years after enrollment, TAA workers would have entered
a more dismal labor market relative to matched UI claimants who may have been reemployed during a
more robust economy after exhausting short-run UI benefits.
14
Second, and consistent with conclusions
from the propensity score literature which calls for a large number of observables for internal validity
(Todd (2010)), the authors recognize that unobserved heterogeneity may result in differently selected
samples across the two groups. In this paper, I contribute direct causal estimates of how training
programs affect worker mobility across local labor markets and industries.
The third literature relates to imperfect spatial and industrial mobility. Pioneering work by Blanchard
and Katz (1992) highlighted the empirical importance of worker mobility as an equilibrating factor across
differently shocked labor markets, and has been by studies on the effects of mobility constraints on
workers. These questions have been studied in the context of migratory insurance during recessions
(Yagan (2014)), responses to trade shocks ((Dix-Carneiro and Kovak, 2017; Bartik A., 2017; Kovak et
al., 2017)), and in the context of place-based policies and taxation (Serrato-Su
´
arez and Zidar (2016),
Kline and Moretti (2014, 2013)). In a theoretical paper analyzing trade compensation in a general
equilibrium framework, Feenstra and Lewis (1994) build on the work of Dixit and Norman (1986) and
show that redistributive compensation from levying taxes on winning factors are more likely to result in
a Pareto-improving allocation if combined with mobility subsidies to overcome adjustment frictions. In
these and other papers, relaxing the benchmark of a perfectly elastic labor supply across regions, sectors,
and occupations, generate myriad frictions which are only now beginning to be tested empirically.
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides institutional background on Trade
Adjustment Assistance, worker eligibility for benefits, and the composition of training programs taken
up. In Section 3, I discuss the main administrative data sources used, matching procedures and sample
restrictions. Section 4 outlines the investigator leniency identification strategy and estimating equations.
Section 5 presents the main results on worker-level outcomes, and heterogeneous mobility and training
intensity effects. I contextualize these results in a cost-benefit analysis in Section 6, presenting the internal
rate of return of TAA and sensitivity to assumptions. Section 7 concludes.
14
Standard UI benefits typically last for 26 weeks, however during the Great Recession both generosity and duration were
greatly expanded.
6
2 Trade Adjustment Assistance
When considerations of national policy make it desirable to avoid higher tariffs, those injured by
that competition should not be required to bear the full brunt of the impact. Rather, the burden
of economic adjustment should be borne in part by the Federal Government... But the accent is
on “adjustment” more than “assistance”. Through trade adjustment prompt and effective help can
be given to those suffering genuine hardship in adjusting to import competition, moving men and
resources of uneconomic production into efficient production and competitive positions...
John F. Kennedy, Congressional address on the 1962 Trade Expansion Act (originally cited by Kondo (2013))
15
2.1 Institutional Background
US Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) is a federal transfer program established under the 1962 Trade
Expansion Act which provides assistance to workers “who lose their jobs or whose hours of work and
wages are reduced as a result of increased imports or shifts in production out of the United States.”
16
The program was established during the Kennedy Round of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT), and sought to couple unprecedented trade liberalization (part of a more widespread post-war
trade integration effort) with adjustment insurance for adversely affected US workers.
The current program is governed by the 1974 Trade Act, and was amended several times throughout
the 1980s altering the generosity of its benefits. In 1993, TAA was expanded to add additional coverage
for workers directly affected by the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA-TAA), however
this provision was subsequently repealed in the Trade Act of 2002. Since 2002 however, TAA benefits
have remained relatively stable in expenditure terms. In fiscal year 2010, nearly $1 billion in annual cash
transfers were appropriated to subsidize an estimated 230,000 qualified workers to enroll in retraining
programs after trade-related layoffs.
17
While TAA contains several program components, its primary
benefit is coverage of training costs for every year a qualified worker is retraining, up to a statutory
maximum of three years. Median annual coverage from 2001 to 2016 was $7,500/recipient-year,
including up to two years for “basic” retraining, and an additional year for “remedial” training (if
deemed necessary) or “completion” training for workers who are close to completing a credentialed
curriculum but have exhausted basic benefits.
Recipients are also entitled to expanded unemployment insurance (UI) benefits while training (called
“Trade Readjustment Allowances” (TRA)), conditional on providing regular proof of training enrollment.
15
Institutional details in this section build on those presented in Monarch et al. (2017) and Kondo (2013), and are amended
based on secondary sources and interviews with Office of Trade Adjustment Assistance officials.
16
Department of Labor, Employment and Training Administration. https://www.doleta.gov/tradeact/taa_wdp.cfm
17
Department of Labor, Employment and Training Administration. https://www.doleta.gov/tradeact/factsheet.cf.
7
This conditional incentive design is distinct from standard UI, in that it intends to overcome moral
hazard concerns associated with search disincentives, imposing at least minimal “search effort” through
job training.
18
Workers are eligible for extended UI for up to three years, including the standard initial
26-week UI duration which is most common across US states. Median receipts on extended UI roughly
equaled $15,000/recipient-year from 2001 to 2016, roughly double the $7,500/recipient-year median
offered for training.
19
Lastly, TAA covers 90% of job search and relocation costs, yet these comprise
less than 0.1% of total spending, and are hence given little attention throughout the analysis.
20
TAA funds are allocated via state transfers to Cooperating State Agencies (CSAs) from the Federal
Unemployment Benefits and Allowances (FUBA) account. Once workers are approved for TAA, state
career centers (e.g. American Job Centers, One-Stop Career Centers) guide workers to potential training
program matches based on prior experience. However, workers ultimately have choice over where
to train. Once they have demonstrated proof of enrollment, both training subsidies and regular TRA
payments are administered through local state career centers, where workers recoup paychecks.
2.2 Worker Eligibility
To receive TAA benefits, workers (or their surrogates) must file petitions at the USDOL within one year
of their trade-related separation from a given employer. Filers may include groups of three or more
workers (38% of total filers), companies filing on behalf of laid off workers (36%), labor unions (13%),
or state career centers (13%).
21
From 1974 to 2016, the USDOL received petitions covering an estimated
8.2 million workers, of which approximately 63% were approved for TAA (see Figure 2). Petitions were
filed on behalf of workers from more than 40,000 unique plants, and the number of approved applicants
began to outstrip denied applicants after the passage of NAFTA.
22
Once a petition is filed at USDOL, Office of Trade Adjustment Assistance supervisors (“certifying
officers”) assign petitions to case investigators working from the Washington D.C. headquarters.
23
(This
assignment process is described in greater detail in the identification strategy in Section 4.) These
investigators are tasked with subjectively determining whether applicants were laid off by companies
whose decline in production (sales) was due to increased imports or outsourcing, and have subpoena
power to request confidential information from any given firm or plant to assess whether its separated
18
Workers near retirement age however, may not find time and effort costs of training to be a high trade-off for extended UI.
19
The extent of this support varies formulaicly by each state’s initial UI generosity. Data used for this calculation comes
from the Trade Act Participant Report (TAPR) from 2001 to 2016. See Appendix B.5 for more details.
20
TAA has also been experimenting with wage insurance to bridge the income gap for older workers, however this program
(know as Alternative or Reemployment TAA) is beyond the scope of the current project.
21
Percentages from author calculations based on USDOL petition data, 1974 - 2016.
22
Figure 2 also demonstrates a countercyclical filing pattern. However this may be unsurprising, as firms have been shown
to make structural adjustments precisely during recessions (Aghion et al., 2005).
23
The short TAA petition form can be found here: https://www.doleta.gov/tradeact/docs/RevisedPetition.pdf
8
workers qualify for TAA.
24
To qualify, investigators look for one of three criteria:
(1) Direct reduction in sales from import competition
(2) Shifts in production outside the US
(3) Upstream supplier or downstream client of firms affected by (1) or (2)
25
Importantly, once investigators certify a petition associated with a given plant, all workers displaced
from that plant within a specified 3-year eligibility window automatically qualify for TAA, despite who
files. The timeline below illustrates this point, and shows which displaced workers are eligible for TAA
based on a statutory window around the petition determination date (event time τ = 0). When a petition
is filed, investigators record the “impact date” as the date a worker-cohort was laid off due to a trade
event, which may not exceed one year prior to when the petition is filed. The “expiry date” marks the last
day a worker can be laid off and still receive benefits—statutorily two years after the petition decision.
τ
1
0 2
τ
TAA Eligibility Window
(displaced workers)
Analysis
Sample
Distorted
Firing
Incentives
τ = 1: TAA “Impact Date” ( Displacement Date)
τ = 0: TAA Determination Date (Approve/Deny)
τ = 2: TAA Eligibility Expiry Date
In corresponding Census microdata, I thus identify my sample as all “displaced” workers that
move from positive to non-positive earnings at a petition-associated plant, within the TAA eligibility
window.
26
One unintended consequence of this eligibility design is that the plant itself may become
aware of its workers’ TAA approval status after the decision is made public at τ = 0. If so, firms
with union-represented workforces or those located in “company-towns” may have an incentive to fire
additional workers who were originally retained after the first wave of layoffs, with the knowledge that
these workers will be compensated.
27
Because retained workers are presumably selected for higher
productivity and would only be laid off if approved for TAA, this could contaminate the treatment group
24
Investigators do this by issuing Confidential Data Requests: https://www.doleta.gov/tradeact/pdf/CDR_Service.pdf,
and typically arrive at a determination decision within 60 days.
25
Upstream suppliers and downstream clients have qualified since 2002.
26
The main results are robust to a number of sensitivity samples that use alternative definitions of displacement that more
closely follow the “mass layoff” literature. These are discussed further in the sample restrictions outlined in Section 3.
27
Whether the motive is profit or non-profit rooted, as noted above, most petitions are filed by companies instituting layoffs
rather than workers or unions.
9
and bias earnings estimates upwards. I thus only include workers laid off in the one year prior to the
petition decision. Despite this relatively conservative condition, I am still able to identify a final sample
of roughly 300,000 displaced workers after sampling restrictions.
28
While the treatment is effectively
at the plant-level, this does not guarantee that information about TAA eligibility disseminates to all
qualified workers. However, it does allow for the estimation of an intent-to-treat (ITT) estimator which
reflects the effects of qualifying for TAA despite potential program shortcomings such as information
asymmetries. Indeed, Schochet et al. (2012) estimate that 25-45% of workers offered TAA benefits
actually take up the program. In combination with the additional restriction above to preclude perverse
incentive problems, these are important limitations when interpreting local average treatment effects
and weighing program benefits against costs.
2.3 TAA Training Programs
The USDOL classifies training by three main categories: occupational (vocational, trade schools,
community college, associates degree, etc.), remedial (elementary proficiency), and work-based training
(including on-the-job, customized, and apprentice training at the firm from which the worker separated
if rehiring in a different occupation post-training).
29
According to TAA performance data from 2000
to 2016, 62% of TAA workers enrolled in occupational training programs, 18% in community college
and credentialed programs, 15% in remedial programs, and less than 1% in work-based (on-the-job and
apprentice) training programs (Trade Act Participant Report).
For a subset of this data (2001 to 2007), I am able to observe the most targeted post-training
occupations and most frequent occupational transitions using USDOL-ascribed occupational codes
(O*Net 4.0 8-digit codes). Consistent with expanding industries during this period, the most targeted
occupations from TAA training were computer operators, office clerks, transcribing-machine operators,
medical assistants, and nursing aids. In terms of occupation switching, some workers choose training
programs to deepen industry-specific human capital, while others appear to enroll in training to expand
general human capital. For example, two of the most commonly displaced occupations during this
period were commercial aircraft workers and men’s clothing workers. Many commercial aircraft workers
retrained in areas that seem like natural transitions—becoming tractor operators and air conditioning or
refrigeration mechanics. However, another popularly targeted occupation among this same group was
medical assistants. Men’s clothing workers on the other hand, frequently retrained to become sewing
machine operators—choosing almost exclusively to deepen knowledge in their incumbent industries.
28
Alternatively, if TAA certification is viewed as negative publicity, certified plants may lay off fewer higher-skilled workers
post-certification, resulting in downward bias from the control plants’ composition of higher-skilled separating workers.
29
While firms can be reimbursed directly for providing on-the-job training to laid-off workers, this comprises a very small
share of overall TAA training activities.
10
3 Data Sources and Matching
This project uses two main administrative datasets, merging the history of TAA petitions to U.S. Census
Bureau administrative data.
3.1 TAA Historical Petition Database
I have first acquired the universe of approved and denied TAA petitions (1974-2016) through Freedom
of Information Act (FOIA) requests at the USDOL. This dataset contains an observation for each petition
(roughly 84,000 in total),
30
and provides three critical pieces of information.
1. First, each petition contains the plant (establishment) name and address, which I leverage for
matching to Census Bureau establishments and the workers employed at those establishments.
2. Each petition contains a series of dates, including the petition filing date, determination (TAA
approval decision) date, impact date, and eligibility expiry date (see Section 2 for definitions).
These are used for identifying and pulling the set of workers laid off in the eligibility window.
3. Crucially for the paper’s main identification strategy, each petition also contains the last name of
the investigator assigned to each case. These names were intensively cleaned in close consult with
DOL officials and validated with historical employee records.
31
The petition database additionally includes information on petitioner filer types (company, union,
worker-group, or state career center), USDOL-assigned 4-digit Standard Industrial Classification (SIC)
codes, the company’s main product or service (recorded as a qualitative value), and an indicator for
whether the petition was designated as part of the NAFTA-TAA program, TAA, or both. Finally, each
petition contains an estimate of the number of workers covered—a 3-year estimate spanning the entire
eligibility window discussed above, that assumes that every laid off worker would take up the program.
Filers come from a variety of industries, from well-known automobile manufacturing plants in
Michigan, to displaced port workers in Seattle. Table 1 shows the location of the top TAA filing zip codes
and the industries associated with those zip codes in each decade of the program’s existence. Moving
from 1975 to 2016, filing has gradually moved from manufacturing industries in “Rust Belt” states to a
more disperse set, both geographically and in terms value-added activities.
30
This includes about 8,400 petitions for the NAFTA-TAA program described in Section 2.
31
This was needed to calculate precise investigator leniency values. For example, this included tasks such as identifying
whether “Green” and “Greene” were the same or separate investigators.
11
3.2 Construction of LEHD Worker-Level Panel
I merge TAA petition data to the US Census Bureau’s Longitudinal Employer-Household Dynamics
(LEHD) administrative files. The LEHD files allow for the construction of a detailed person-level panel
dataset which tracks quarterly worker earnings, labor force participation (employment), and educational
status across employers, geographies, and time. The core data are compiled from employer-reported
Unemployment Insurance (UI) filings at the state-level for every paid employee (ES-202 forms). While
the LEHD data partnership spans all 50 US states and covers over 90% of US workers,
32
states approve
researcher requested data on a state-by-state basis. For this project, 24 states and the District of Columbia
approved data access.
33
I use the 2011 LEHD snapshot which provides a relatively balanced panel from
1990 to 2011 (see Appendix A.1 for further details). Leveraging each worker’s (de-identified) social
security number, I merge in worker age, gender, and race, from the Social Security Administration
Numident file (available in the LEHD Individual Characteristics File). Educational attainment variables
are also available for Decennial Census and American Community Survey (ACS) respondents (roughly
1 in 6 workers), while education imputes based on Census Bureau multiple-imputation and probabilistic
record linking methods are used for non-respondent workers.
34
Education can take four ordinal values:
1=Some High School; 2=High School Degree; 3=Some College; 4=College Degree.
There are some important caveats imposed by the data limitations discussed above. Figure 3
compares the number of estimated TAA workers covered by filed petitions in all states (cumulated
over the entire TAA history from 1974 to 2016), against the number of filers in the 24-state LEHD
sub-sample from 1990 to 2011. These are mapped to 1990 Commuting Zone (CZs) geographies, which
are the central unit of analysis when measuring the effects of TAA on spatial mobility.
35
The figure
reveals that while filers are generally concentrated in “Rust Belt” and southern manufacturing states,
the LEHD sub-sample is missing some notable political swing states such as Michigan, Wisconsin, and
Ohio (however contain others such as Pennsylvania).
Secondly, as is the case in most labor settings however, the LEHD cannot distinguish between a
number of cases that may be the cause of a missing earnings value. Following standard practice, I
designate a worker as unemployed if she has a missing earnings value between two positive earnings
observations. However I cannot discern between unemployed workers versus those who are retired,
32
As part of the non-included 10%, the LEHD excludes workers who are self-employed, agricultural workers, and some
government employees. See Abowd et al. (2009) and Vilhuber and McKinney (2014) for further details.
33
These include AR, AZ, CA, CO, DC, DE, FL, IA, ID, IL, IN, KS, MD, ME, MO, MT, NM, NV, OK, OR, PA, SC, TN, WA, WV.
34
All effects of TAA on formal education are robust to using both imputed and non-imputed measures. It also bears noting
that while worker occupations are available for ACS respondents, these data were not made available for the current draft
however will be explored in future work.
35
Using the definition from Dorn (2009), “Commuting Zones (CZs) provide a local labor market geography that covers the
entire land area of the United States. CZs are clusters of U.S. counties that are characterized by strong within-cluster and weak
between-cluster commuting ties.“
12
deceased, reliant on extended take-up of social insurance programs such as disability insurance,
self-employed, or discouraged from the labor force. Importantly, I also cannot know whether a worker
with a missing earnings value is in fact employed in a state outside of the set of 24 approved for this
project. This limitation would be most problematic for mobility estimates. In robustness tests, I thus
show that the main effects are stable when using the more contiguous West Coast states shown in Figure
3 which are less likely to feature mobility outside of the region.
3.3 Matching TAA Petitions to Displaced Workers at LEHD Employers
To be able to detect a potentially small effect size of TAA in noisy earnings data, I desire as conservative
a matching strategy as possible. To identify TAA filers at the worker-level, I first have to identify both
the correct TAA petitioner plants and the timing of the separation event in the LEHD.
Beginning with identifying TAA plants, the 2011 LEHD snapshot contains each establishment’s State
Employer Identification Number (SEIN) and federal Employer Identification Number (EIN), however
does not directly report business name and address.
36
Using commingled IRS and Census data from the
Business Register—the Census Bureau’s most comprehensive database of U.S. business establishments
(formerly Standard Statistical Establishment List)—I am able to assign a company name and address to
each EIN in the LEHD, and subsequently match LEHD plants to TAA petitioners on cleaned company
names and addresses.
I keep only the first TAA petition associated with any given plant so that no worker is assigned
to both the treatment and control group due to multiple filings. I then match TAA plant addresses to
Business Register addresses in both the calendar year of the petition and the year prior to the petition
(to account for any potential filing lags or measurement error in filing dates).
37
Finally, I keep matched
LEHD establishments if the plant address is unique to a given state-year cell. By focusing on one-to-one
matches, this circumvents problems arising from matching one TAA establishment address to a Census
location containing many establishments at the same address (such as an office building). The sample
should thus be interpreted as representative of rural, stand-alone, manufacturing plants. I then repeat
this exact same procedure for company names, extensively cleaned in both datasets.
Drawing three random samples of 100 TAA petitions, I manually cross-check company names and
addresses and verify a match rate of 98%, with the residual likely owing to discrepancies between parent
and subsidiary names which could not be reconciled between the two datasets. This results in a final
matched sample of 4,700 unique TAA establishments—comprising roughly 13% of plants associated
36
Each EIN and SEIN may have multiple and distinct units. For details on how this is dealt with, see Appendix A.1.
37
I build a comprehensive address cleaning file based on other papers, including code generously provided by Monarch et
al. (2017) who also match TAA plants to Business Register addresses.
13
with TAA claimants from 1990 to 2011. Finally, each matched plant’s SEIN number can then be used
to pull all workers employed at those plants during the eligibility window described in Section 2.2.
The final step is to pull the full job history for each of these workers, and identify which workers
separated or were “displaced”—defined here as moving from positive non-positive earnings during
the TAA eligibility window.
38
For further details on this procedure, please see Appendix A.1.
3.4 Sample Restrictions and Summary Statistics
Having identified TAA-eligible displaced workers associated with both approved and denied petitions,
I implement a number of sample restrictions to focus on those who are most likely to take up training
were they randomly assigned TAA approval. As noted in Section 2.2, I keep workers only if they
were displaced in the year prior to the petition decision, which eliminates one third of the original
sample. I further restrict attention to working-age individuals (22-65) who make less than $50,000/year
(85th percentile) in all years prior to the petition filing. This value is a commonly used threshold for
Department of Labor programs, and eliminates the spurious inclusion of CEOs, managers, and other
workers who are both unlikely to take up training and not the population of interest in this study.
Quarterly earnings are deflated to 2010 real dollars using a seasonally adjusted consumer price
index. For computational tractability, I further collapse worker earnings to the year relative to the
petition decision (event time τ). While workers can furnish returns from multiple employers, earnings
are aggregated such that each worker only has one earnings observation per relative year (the unit of
analysis). I include observations 10 years before and after the petition decision such that τ [10, 10] .
39
These restrictions reduce the overall dataset from 25 million to 4.2 million observations and 287,000
workers (rounded as per Census Bureau disclosure requirements). Earnings and employment values are
left- and right-censored within each worker panel, however the main paper results are robust to both
censoring and replacing edge values with zeros.
Lastly, for comparability with the labor literature, I define a “High Labor Force Attachment”
sub-group as the preferred analysis sample of the paper. This includes workers with at least 8 quarters
of positive earnings in the pre-period at or above the full-time minimum wage equivalent ($7.25 * 2,082
average working hours in 2010 $15,000 annually).
40
This results in a final sample of 177,000 displaced
workers. However, all main results are robust to using both the high attachment sub-sample and the
unrestricted sample.
38
Workers can furnish returns from multiple employers, but earnings are aggregated (collapsed) such that each worker only
has one earnings observation per quarter.
39
This window takes maximal advantage of the 21 years of data spanned by the LEHD.
40
Further restrictions on the petitioner side include keeping only those petitions assigned to investigators with more than
10 cases, to eliminate potential noise associated with investigator leniency rates calculated from small cells.
14
Table 2 shows summary statistics for both groups, pooled across all periods (pre-period balance
statistics are presented in the next table). Starting with panel A, workers in both samples are largely
middle-aged, predominantly white, and slightly skewed toward being female. Worker high school and
college graduation rates are almost exactly in line with national averages for the time period.
41
Because
they are included based on a separation event, worker earnings and quarters employed per year are
expectedly below national averages, with the average worker making $22,830 and $18,814 in each sample
respectively (see panel B). Workers have on average about 1 job, however there is large dispersion in the
worker’s total number of employers in a given year. As indicated by the county unemployment rate at
the time of filing, these workers are in highly distressed local labor markets with unemployment rates
near 6.5% (BLS Local Area Unemployment Statistics).
I also report overall mobility rates expressed as the likelihood a worker remains at the firm,
industry, or commuting zone of the employer from which they initially separated. Regarding petitioner
characteristics (panel C), companies and worker-groups are the most common filers, followed by unions.
It bears noting that approval rates are much higher when companies file with respect to non-company
filers, which can be seen by comparing “TAA Approved” versus “TAA Denied” groups in either sample.
Both samples contain roughly 250 case investigators during this time period, who remain on average
for about 10 years with the Department of Labor and handle roughly 23 TAA cases over that tenure. To
see the extent to which approval rates map to standard measures of industry tradability and occupational
offshorability associated with those industries (presumably known to investigators), I merge in three
known indices from Mian and Sufi (2014), Autor and Dorn (2013), and Blinder (2007), which show that
higher tradability values are generally associated with the approved TAA groups. For details on their
construction at the industry-level, see Appendix A.2.
4 Empirical Framework
4.1 Limitations to Difference-in-Differences
The top panel of Figure 4 plots raw means for TAA approved and denied workers across their separation
events, relative to the year of the petition decision (τ = 0). At first glance, one might look at this
figure and conclude that workers who are approved for TAA are observably no different than those that
are denied in the pre-period. The difference-in-differences (DID) common trends assumption appears
to hold visually, and thus we are tempted to interpret the post-period (lack of) differential earnings
response as a causal effect. However this is highly misleading for at least two reasons.
41
Ryan and Siebens (2012) show that post-1990 high school graduation rates were roughly 80%—consistent with adding the
three education values in the summary statistics—whereas college graduation rates were roughly 25%.
15
First, these means mask incredible heterogeneity in both levels and pre-trends. To see this, Appendix
B.1 expresses mean earnings differences between certified and denied TAA applicants by 2-digit SIC
codes (thin gray lines), overlaid with the aggregate difference from the top panel of Figure 4 (bold series).
Firstly, the figure shows a mild downward trend in overall earnings differences which likely reflects
wage declines in tradable production, and at the very least, warrants within-industry comparisons to
control for selection on tradability and its correlates. Even within industries however, we see both
positively and negatively selected pre-trends. In textiles for example, TAA approved workers exhibit
both differentially declining earnings and a lower level of overall earnings relative to non-TAA approved
workers, which might bias TAA effects downwards. Whereas in other support industries such as
aluminum manufacturing products and auto parts, TAA-approved pre-treatment earnings are much
higher than non-TAA earnings, which might bias TAA effects upwards. The overall point is there is
no good reason that approved workers should look like denied workers absent TAA. Secular trends for
workers at “tradable” goods plants confound post estimates.
Second and more subtle, even if the common pretrends assumption appeared to hold visually after
conditioning on covariates, TAA workers may respond differentially to the layoff event itself, relative to
non-TAA workers. Those working at non-tradable goods plants for example, may have a broader skill set
that would be more transferable after layoff to an automating plant. Or, plants producing tradable goods
may have higher union representation which may result in earnings looking similar pre-separation, but
may lead to differential preparedness for industry and occupational switching post-separation. In both
cases, one would need an even stronger visual test such as parallel post-trends absent the treatment, which
is not possible to test (even if these are necessary but not sufficient conditions for identification). Overall,
workers may be different for a number of reasons correlated with tradability, geography, demographics,
or heterogeneity in access to types of training, yielding DID estimates that are likely not credible.
4.2 Investigator Assignment and Leniency IV
TAA cases are assigned [to investigators] primarily based on investigator caseload, as well as previous
experience with a company or industry. Staff leave or other scheduling issues can be a factor as well.
Correspondence with Office of Trade Adjustment Assistance,
a (obtained via Department of Labor FOIA request, 12/15/2016)
To overcome the challenging selection problems involved in identifying the causal effects of TAA, I take
advantage of how petitions are assigned to case investigators. I define an investigator’s leniency as the
share of total cases approved over their entire tenure, less the current case (excluding those with less
16
than 10 cases over their tenure).
42
This “leave-one-out” leniency measure (also known as a“jackknife”
IV) thus varies by investigator and case, but is time-invariant.
43
According to the assignment mechanism described in the quote above, TAA assigns two otherwise
identical worker cohorts displaced from the same industry, different TAA approval probabilities
based on whether their case is directed to a more lenient versus strict investigator. I thus use this
leave-one-out measure of investigator leniency as an instrumental variable (IV) for assignment to TAA.
44
Yet as leniency may still be correlated with petitioner characteristics through industry specialization
and experience, I must also include a number of flexible controls for each investigator’s industrial
concentration and experience. Conditional on the successful inclusion of these controls, I provide a
number of tests that show assignment based on caseload is effectively as if randomly assigned.
The intuition for how this instrument alters earnings results with respect to the naive DID estimator,
is shown in the bottom panel of Figure 4. Raw earnings are plotted for workers assigned to top and
bottom decile residualized leniency quartiles, obtained by first regressing leave-one-out leniency on
4-digit SIC industry fixed effects, quarter-of-filing fixed effects, and investigator industry concentration
and experience controls at the time of filing (discussed in detail in the next section). Purging the IV of
these threats to randomization, the resulting plot is a conditional version of the “reduced form equation”
of a corresponding 2SLS procedure. Comparing means for workers assigned to very lenient (top decile)
versus very strict (bottom decile) investigator scores, we begin to see earnings patterns separate in the
post-period and flatten in the pre-period. While these deciles reflect one moment of the data (preferred
estimates scale up the results by the inverse of the first stage using the whole support of residualized
leniency), the plot illustrates the variation underlying the main results of the paper.
42
For a subset of years, the petition also lists the last name of the certifying officer who assigned the case. For those cases, I
calculate leniency across investigator-certifier cells, however all results are robust to using investigator cells alone, in addition
to investigator-certifying officer cells.
43
Additional results show that investigator leniency is relatively stable within investigators over time. DOL investigators
do work on a number of cases beyond those associated with TAA, including for example Occupational Safety and Health
Administration (OSHA) cases. However these are not observed in the data and thus not included in the leniency measure.
44
While investigator leniency is the most, Belloni et al. (2012) propose a lasso method for selecting the most strongly
binding among a number of plausibly exogenous instruments. However in this paper, the only other investigator-level variable
available is an imputed investigator race variable based on last name, and I thus do not employ this method.
17
4.3 Estimation Strategy
I employ a two-stage least squares (2SLS) estimation strategy that tracks workers as they move across
employers using repeated (pooled) cross-sectional regressions over event time:
TAA
ijkt
= θLeniency
p
j(i)
+ α
1
C
jkt
+ δ
1
N
jkt
+ λ
k
+ X
0
ijkt
γ
1
+ ν
ijkt
(1)
Y
ijktτ
= β
τ
TAA
ijkt
+ α
2
C
jkt
+ δ
2
N
jkt
+ λ
k
| {z }
restoring randomness
+X
0
ijkt
γ
2
+ e
ijktτ
(2)
In the first stage, worker i’s petition is assigned to investigator j in calendar year t. TAA
ijkt
is an indicator
variable equal to 1 if that worker is associated with an approved TAA petition.
45
Leniency
p
j(i)
measures
the total share of cases approved by investigator j less the worker’s own petition p.
46
k indexes the
4-digit SIC industry from which the worker was displaced, and τ [10, 10] is the year relative to the
petition approval decision at τ = 0. Outcomes Y
ijktτ
include worker earnings, quarters employed, formal
education, and the probability workers move 2-digit NAICS industries and commuting zones.
I include three assignment variables to control flexibly for differential approval propensities among
highly specialized or experienced investigators. N
jkt
is the raw number of cases that an investigator j
has adjudicated in industry k by calendar year t. C
jkt
=
N
jkt
j
N
jkt
is the concentration of industry k cases
assigned to investigator j by time t. While these may be correlated, they are not perfectly collinear due
to the fact that investigators are not balanced across the entire panel. To the extent that any remaining
unobserved fixed factors at the industry level affect both investigator assignment and underlying worker
characteristics (e.g. geography, mean tradability), fixed effects λ
k
are included, and further ensure that
the impact of TAA is identified from leniency comparisons within narrowly defined industries. In
both stages, X
ijkt
are precision controls that are mostly time-invariant and measured in the baseline
(pre-application) period.
47
The coefficients of interest are each β
τ
, which are estimated in separate regressions for each τ. When
overlaid on an event-study style plot, these point estimates dynamically map out the effects of TAA over
time. Thee include placebo estimates for all τ < 0, which test for the effects of TAA prior to the worker’s
separation and petition for benefits (i.e. periods in which we would not expect to find any statistical
significant differential effects of TAA).
45
I use the subscript j(i) to clarify that worker i is assigned to investigator j (j for “judge”).
46
This estimator is formally known as a “jackknife” IV (JIVE), whose finite sample properties have been explored in a
number of papers (Angrist et al. (1999), Ackerberg and Devereux (2011), Kolesar (2013)). What varies here, is that leniency is
calculated from the universe of petitions, similar to a split sample IV design (Angrist and Kreuger (1995)) with fixed effects.
47
The exception to this is a polynomial in age and variables interacted with that polynomial, however these vary
mechanically over time and cannot be endogenously manipulated in response to the TAA treatment. Not shown in equations
(1) and (2) but indicated clearly in regression tables, calendar-year and filer-quarter fixed effects are included in most
specifications.
18
4.4 Randomization Tests and IV Assumptions
Like all instrumental variables, the leniency IV must satisfy three main conditions to recover a local
average treatment effect (LATE): excludability, relevance, and monotonicity (Imbens and Angrist, 1994).
Before turning to tests for these conditions however, it is useful to consider TAA approval as the latent
outcome of a selection model to understand why the quasi-experimental controls above are included.
Consider a simple model of TAA selection similar to the second stage in the above 2SLS procedure:
Y
ijktτ
= β
τ
{σ
k
+ Z
j(i)k
+ X
0
ijkt
> ξ
ijkt
} + e
ijktτ
(3)
Here, the approval indicator TAA
ijkt
is determined by whether the latent sum of three components
exceeds an unobservable worker-investigator admittance threshold ξ
ijkt
. First, leniency is assumed
separable into an investigator-industry shift (Z
j(i)k
) around an industry’s average tradability signal
σ
k
(the industry approval rate shared by all investigators). Observable characteristics X
0
ijkt
for both
workers and investigators at the time of petition filing further capture investigator experience terms.
A linear parametrization of this equation yields the 2SLS reduced form equation, where the inclusion
of λ
k
fixed effects absorb both the independent effect of σ
k
, and demean (within-transform) the
investigator-industry specific leniency to yield an industry-invariant leniency measure.
Y
ijktτ
= b
1τ
Leniency
p
j(i)
+ λ
k
+ b
2τ
X
0
ijkt
+ e
ijktτ
(4)
For b
1τ
(the numerator of the 2SLS estimate) to be identified without the second term, λ
k
would need
to be uncorrelated with both the investigator’s leniency and industry-specific earnings. However we
have already seen that earnings levels vary dramatically by industry, and know institutionally that
highly concentrated investigators are assigned to specific industries. To the extent that this happens
in a transitory and not fixed way, time-varying investigator concentration controls are also included in
X
0
ijkt
(though these turn out not to have much of an effect).
48
Excludability
While excludability cannot be tested directly, I present two strong pieces of evidence supporting
the claim that investigator leniency is orthogonal to pre-determined characteristics of petitioners
48
The choice of the level of aggregation of SIC fixed effects and concentration controls depend on a trade-off between bias
and efficiency. The more narrow the industry grouping, the more likely differences in tradability and its correlates are controlled
for, but the less precise our estimates become due to sparser observations of approved and denied cases in each grouping. In
practice, I require a minimum of 10 approved and denied cases per investigator to be included in the regression. Robustness to
control choices are shown in Appendix C.2.
19
(conditional on concentration controls and fixed effects), and that the instrument only affects worker
outcomes through assignment to TAA.
In Table 3, I test for random assignment of TAA petitions to DOL investigators by regressing the
instrument on pre-determined characteristics. If investigators were assigned to cases with particular
economic or demographic characteristics, we would expect to observe statistically significant predictors
of higher leniency values. However, as we move through the columns from left to right, consistent
with randomization, very few covariates are predictive of the instrument. (When they are statistically
significant, the coefficients are economically so close to zero that they can be ignored.)
Starting with column (1), I report the baseline mean of all pre-determined characteristics prior to the
eligibility window (5 to 40 quarters before the petition decision inclusively). The dependent variable in
column (2) is the endogenous TAA approval indicator variable. Consequently, it is not surprising that
many of the coefficients in this column are statistically significant. Notably, in panel C, company filers
have approval rates that are on average 22 percentage points higher than the omitted filer group (state
career centers), and TAA approved workers are more likely to be considered “tradable” according to the
Mian and Sufi (2014) definition.
The dependent variable in columns (3) to (5) is the investigator leniency IV. Columns (4) and (5)
add the three “randomness restoring” controls shown in the main specification, where investigator
concentration controls include both C
jkt
and N
jkt
measures (defined above). Adding these controls
only alter randomization results in minor ways—consistent with most variation being driven by
caseload-based assignment within industry, rather than time-varying industry assignment.
49
Since
the regressions presented here each include many covariates however, one may be concerned that the
oversaturation of the model with controls is what drives the zeros, rather than random assignment.
Column (6) thus shows p-values from separate regressions of the leniency IV on each covariate
independently. Here, as in all regressions, standard errors are clustered at the investigator level (the
level of randomization). Finally, all regressions contain quarter-of-filing and calendar-year fixed effects.
The second piece of evidence that assignment based on caseload is as if random, is that investigators
with low caseloads do not systematically differ in their leniencies from investigators with higher
caseloads. Figure 5 demonstrates non-parametrically, how neither investigator caseload nor tenure at the
Department of Labor are correlated with leniency. This rules out confounding stories such as cases being
assigned to more experienced investigators who regularly approve certain types of workers, or the idea
that lower caseload workers have different competencies which could be correlated with pre-determined
characteristics of the types of workers they approve—violating the exclusion restriction.
49
The movement from statistically significant to insignificant baseline covariates is sharper when testing for balance within
any given relative year. This is shown in detail in Appendix C.2.
20
Relevance, First Stage, and Monotonicity
Figure 6 displays variation in the investigator leniency measure pooled across the program’s history, and
matched to the final analysis sample. The top panel is obtained by first regressing leniency on the three
quasi-experimental controls discussed above (added to the overall sample leniency for interpretation).
I then plot the number of petitions filed across bins of this residualized leniency, which exhibits a
surprising degree of variation (kernal bandwidth and 5% tails withheld for confidentiality). The plot
is then overlaid with a local linear regression of approval rates on residualized leniency to demonstrate
the first stage with respect to the underlying variation. The bottom panel then compares this to a “raw”
(unresidualized) leniency measure in the data.
Table 4 reports companion first stage estimates corresponding to equation (1) of the paper for the
“High Labor Force Attachment” sample. Column (1) includes the minimal set of controls needed for
identification, while moving left to right adds precision controls and investigator characteristics (which
have already been shown to be uncorrelated with approval rates in Figure 5.) Baseline Controls include
means over 5 to 40 quarters prior to the TAA petition decision for the following variables: worker
earnings, quarters employed, worker tenure, and initial employer and state earnings. Full Regression
Controls reflect covariates estimated in the preferred specification in subsequent tables, and include: race
and gender fixed effects, a cubic in age fully interacted with baseline earnings and gender indicators,
filer-state fixed effects, filer-type fixed effects (company, union, worker-group), and a dummy variable
for whether a petition applied as part of the NAFTA-TAA program.
Interpreting the magnitude of the first stage, a coefficient of 0.60 can be interpreted as a 10 percentage
point increase in leniency (the share of cases approved) being associated with a 6 percentage point higher
approval rate. I report the F-statistic from an F-test on the excluded instrument, which is consistently
strong and robust despite conservative clustering. I report unadjusted F-statistics as leniencies are
measured from the entire history of investigators, and not estimated (consistent with the examiner
literature that does not adjust degrees of freedom). Finally, the data shown here use the main analysis
sample at the worker-level. When regressions corresponding to models (1) and (2) are estimated at the
petition-level using just petition data however, the first stage coefficient is closer to 1, a coefficient which
is also routinely found in the examiner literature).
50
Overall, these results suggest that the instrument
indeed has a large amount of predictive power over worker approval for TAA.
Finally, I explore monotonicity. While the monotonicity assumption is difficult to test explicitly, I
follow common practices in labor economics and confirm that heterogeneous subgroups of the analysis
all contain a positive first stage such that higher leniency scores weakly increase TAA probability,
50
There is also a large increase in the excluded IV first stage F-statistics at the petitioner-level.
21
facilitating a local average treatment effect interpretation for compliers.
LATE Compliers
Before proceeding to the main results of the paper, it is worth highlighting which types of petitioners and
workers are expected to comply with the treatment. Borrowing from earlier notation, each TAA approval
decision can be thought of as a latent variable sum of an observable “tradability” signal σ
k
and subjective
adjudication noise Z
j(i)k
for each investigator j (see Dobbie and Song (2015) for a similar set-up). This is
expressed in Appendix B.2. The left panel orders mean industry approval rates from lowest to highest by
3-digit NAICS codes, calculated over all TAA cases from 1974 to 2016. These are highly correlated with
known measures of tradability. The right panel shows within-industry investigator variation around
the same mean approval rates, where the median is indicated with a black dot and range plot whiskers
reflect the 35th to 65th leniency percentiles within each industry.
The high-variance industries along the middle bracket of the support reflect the “marginal” cases
that are hard to adjudicate, and for whom the randomly assigned investigator is most likely to be
influential. Roughly 80% of workers are assigned to investigators with leniency rates between 0.2 and
0.8, which suggests that indeed most TAA applicants are not part of industries that are easily assessable
as having been impacted by offshoring or import competition. This raises an important concern about
the extent to which the results remain relevant to trade-shocked workers. If indeed industry tradability
is hard to adjudicate, the local average treatment effect may in fact represent the effects of training on a
different population rather than workers most adversely affected by trade. For example, if trade shocks
are correlated with technological upgrading or automation, the LATE will reflect some combination of
these. In additional results, I parse estimates by different regions of this support and find no significant
differences across low and high values of tradability.
Lastly, it is important to note that the LATE estimated here is in fact an intent-to-treat estimator which
mechanically understates the treatment-on-treated or “true” LATE. Without detailed take-up data at the
individual or plant-level however, one cannot conduct the desired bounding or decomposition exercises
that would help place these effects in a more general context, nor use intent to instrument for take-up as
is common with one-sided compliance models.
22
5 Main Results
5.1 Impact of TAA on Worker Earnings, Employment, and Formal Education
Table 5 reports the main effects of TAA on worker earnings using the regression specified in equation (2),
where event time τ is pooled across two periods (such that each row represents a separate regression):
Pre-Training: τ [10, 1]; and Post-Training: τ [2, 10].
51
Starting with the post period, column (1)
shows baseline OLS estimates that are negative and statistically significant, suggesting that TAA workers
receive on average $964 lower annual earnings after training. However, this estimate is not credible for
the myriad of reasons discussed above. When applying the leniency instrument in a 2SLS approach
in columns (2) through (6), the effect sign and magnitude dramatically change. Column (6) shows the
preferred TAA earnings estimate of the paper. Accordingly, TAA takers have on average $10,256 higher
annual earnings, relative to all-else-equal non-takers.
52
Successively adding precision controls from columns (2) to (6) only minorly alter effect sizes.
Particularly influential in reducing standard errors are controls added from columns (4) to (6). These
are potential signs that TAA effects may have important dimensions of heterogeneity by filer type, local
labor market (including states), and demographics. Lastly, consistent with prior randomization results,
the pre-training period placebo estimates consistently show a precise zero. That is, there are assuringly
no differential earnings effects of TAA when we not expect there to be (prior to the worker’s separation).
Considering average baseline earnings prior to layoffs were $26,880 (Table 3), an effect size of
$10,256 implies a relatively large elasticity. To further understand these results, I reestimate equation
(2) separately for each period 10 years before and after the year of the TAA approval decision. The
results for these 21 regressions (using the preferred specification from column (6) of Table 5) are plotted
in the top panel of Figure 7, where vertical lines partition the support into pre-TAA, during-TAA, and
post-TAA periods. The figure shows a clear and surprisingly pattern. Expectedly, workers inferred to
take up benefits forego roughly $10,000 in income while training for two years. Perhaps unexpectedly
however, large initial returns decay over time. Annual incomes among TAA and non-TAA workers in
fact, fully converge after ten years. Further tests reveal that this pattern is not driven by differential
attrition.
51
As the vast majority of program participants enroll in two-year programs or less, I conservatively use this window (rather
than a 3-year training window) as the treatment period. For effects on earnings during training, see Figure 8 which shows more
granular annual effects over event time.
52
Variable definitions are analogous to those shown in Section 4.4. Baseline Controls include means over 5 to 40 quarters
prior to the TAA petition decision for the following variables: worker earnings, quarters employed, worker tenure, and initial
employer earnings. Full Regression Controls reflect covariates estimated in the preferred specification in subsequent tables, and
include: race and gender fixed effects, a cubic in age fully interacted with baseline earnings and gender indicators, filer-state
fixed effects, filer-type fixed effects (company, union, worker-group), and a dummy variable for whether a petition applied
as part of the NAFTA-TAA program. All specifications include the identification controls needed for restoring randomness
according to equation (2), and standard errors are clustered at the investigator level (the level of randomization).
23
Importantly, the dependent variable here includes earnings values equal to zero when a worker is
unemployed, and is thus reflective of the joint earnings and labor force participation effect. To begin to
decompose these two mechanisms and rationalize the pattern of depreciation, the bottom panel of Figure
7 implements the same estimation but calculating the dependent variable as within-worker cumulative
earnings from τ = 10 to the event year on the x-axis on the left, and from τ = 0 on the right.
53
The results from these cumulative earnings regressions suggest that indeed, effects are being driven
by both earnings as well as labor force participation. The advantage to expressing earnings this way
instead of logging, is that one does not need to be concerned with logging earnings values of zero.
Appendix B.4 shows however, that logging produces very similar results. Furthermore, cumulative
earnings have an appealing interpretation. Ten years out, workers have approximately $50,000 higher
cumulative earnings relative to all-else equal workers that do not retrain. This pattern is fully stable to
using the larger “full” sample which does not only restrict attention to workers that were more highly
attached to the labor force (see Appendix B.3 for the corresponding figure, and Appendix C.1 for more
detailed event-year coefficient estimates.)
Table 6 reports the main effects of TAA on number of quarters employed using the same specification
and controls as before. Focusing on the preferred estimate in column (6), TAA-trained workers are
employed on average 0.64 more quarters each year in the post period (τ [2, 10]). The top panel
of Figure 8 shows the corresponding dynamic pattern of employment, which closely mirrors earnings
effects. Trained workers appear immediately more employable than non-trained workers, which further
suggests that there are no economically meaningful extra search costs after TAA workers exhaust
extended UI benefits (a mechanism that we can thus tentatively rule out but return to when discussing
mobility effects). Back-of-the-envelope calculations suggest that roughly 67% of the prior earnings
pattern can be explained by this higher employment rate.
54
While the LEHD does not contain variables
for hours worked, I am able to test whether TAA affects the number of jobs a worker has in a given year.
If displaced workers that do not receive TAA benefits face reduced hours in the labor market, this may
materialize as workers taking multiple part-time jobs. However, the bottom panel of Figure 8 confirms
that there is no discernible effect on the number of jobs held.
If indeed training contributes a sizable benefit that is capitalized into earnings, we may expect to
see differential take-up along formal education measures. Table 7 reports the main effects on two such
measures—the probability a worker has educational attainment greater than or equal to a high school
degree and “some college” respectively. As discussed before, a concerning caveat about this data is that
53
In cumulative earnings regressions, censored values are replaced with zeros.
54
Using denied worker annual earnings as a baseline ($23,468 from Table 2), I divide this by 4 to get quarterly earnings, and
multiply by 0.64 to attain the relative earnings return for each year in the post period (τ [2, 10]). I then calculate this as a
fraction of the cumulative earnings return just established: 33,793.92/50,0000 = .67
24
the measurement is both ordinal and sparsely populated. I show however in the table, that across all
specifications, there is no statistically significant effect on the probability that a worker moves up the
formal education scale. This is robust to using the constrained sample for which education values are
not imputed, and the full sample included education imputes. Figure 9 demonstrates this clearly.
5.2 Heterogeneity and Mechanisms
The fact that TAA appears to increase earnings, that those earnings depreciate, and that there are no
effects on formal education (such as community college take-up), together suggest that TAA may only
augment short-run demanded human capital rather than the types of permanent capital that are known
to have more durable returns (Card (2001); Kane and Rouse (1995)). While there is suggestive evidence
that most effects are coming through training and not extended unemployment components of TAA,
there is also concern that trained workers are just getting bumped to the top of local labor market job
queues at the expense of other workers.
55
One way this might manifest itself is if trained workers stay in
the same industries and labor markets relative to untrained workers. Conversely, if TAA workers switch
industries and labor markets, this is more consistent with an adjustment friction story rather than labor
market crowd-out.
To begin to test these mechanisms, I expand the main regression specification of the paper to account
for simple heterogeneity in pre-TAA characteristics such that regression coefficients reflect within-group
causal effects. In the specification below, I interact the main effects of TAA (mediated by investigator
leniency) with “High” and “Low” values of pre-treatment covariates in both stages.
TAA
ijkt
1(High)
t
= θ
H
1
Leniency
p
j(i)
1(High)
t
+ θ
H
2
Leniency
p
j(i)
1(Low)
t
+ ... + ν
H
ijkt
(5)
TAA
ijkt
1(Low)
t
= θ
L
1
Leniency
p
j(i)
1(High)
t
+ θ
L
2
Leniency
p
j(i)
1(Low)
t
+ ... + ν
L
ijkt
(6)
Y
ijktτ
= β
1τ
TAA
ijkt
1(High)
t
+ β
2τ
TAA
ijkt
1(Low)
t
+ ... + e
ijktτ
(7)
The above specification is analogous to equations (1) and (2), where equations (3) and (4) correspond
to the new first stage. Ellipses (...) are shown to parsimoniously capture exogenous controls αC
jkt
+
δN
jkt
+ λ
k
+ X
0
ijkt
γ in all three equations. Unlike before however, I include 1(High)
t
and 1(Low)
t
as indicator variables for whether a worker is above or below the median of a certain pre-treatment
covariate, as well as interacted calender year and filer-quarter fixed effects so that estimates are
interpreted within subgroups. In this way, one can plot the main coefficients of interest across two
simple heterogeneity groups (β
1τ
and β
2τ
) to test for heterogeneous treatment effects.
55
See Heckman, Stixrud, and Urzua (2006) for a nuanced view of how schooling and job signaling may play out in such
scenarios.
25
Training Quality and Duration
I begin by examining heterogeneity in training quality. While quality is unobservable, the Department
of Labor Trade Act Participant Report (TAPR) records average weeks trained for TAA participants on
a quarter-by-state basis, which varies based on fiscal resources committed to vocational training and
state education programs. Using duration data from 2001 to 2016, I define “High” and “Low” training
states with respect to the median weeks trained per person in each calendar quarter. Figure 10 shows
the overlaid results of the two coefficients of interest, suppressing standard errors for clarity (however
statistical significance is reported in Table 8).
Remarkably, workers that are located in high-duration states prior to their layoff (the series marked
with an “x”) do not exhibit the depreciating pattern that is common to those in lower training duration
states. While one might be concerned that in fact, lower training duration reflects drop-out rates or
other selected worker qualities, it is unlikely that an entire state features large enough selection effects
to explain this difference. In conjunction with previous evidence, I thus attribute the depreciation to
short-run demanded skills becoming obsolete (consistent with rapid skill-biased technological change
or an overall declining labor share).
56
Indeed, 62% of TAA training programs confer vocational degrees
with shorter program lengths than typical community college or 4-year college degrees. Whether these
vocational programs are responsive enough to more rapidly adapt to changing demand, or if instead
more human capital investment is needed to catch up to the frontier, requires more research. However
the results here provide some strong leads for future work in this area.
Effects on Spatial and Industrial Mobility
To analyze effects on worker mobility across commuting zones and industries, I first rank counties by
the severity of their shock based on Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) unemployment rate data (Local
Area Unemployment Statistics), which I merge to the LEHD panel. I define high and low shock severity
regions based on whether the county in which a TAA-qualified worker was displaced was above or
below median unemployment in their quarter of separation.
57
Figure 11 reveals that workers displaced in slacker labor markets (higher unemployment counties)
have returns that are almost double those of low unemployment rate counties. Foregone earnings
are higher for workers in high-shock regions, which suggests they train for longer. However, the
vast majority of workers are located in high-shock counties, which is also evidenced by the summary
statistics. I thus interpret the main effects as being driven by high-shock regions, and subsequently
56
For a discussion of the potential determinants of the declining labor share in the United States, see Autor et al. (2017).
57
All results here are robust to using a level measure of local labor market distress, or a change over time.
26
examine high and low shocks separately when analyzing mobility effects.
Figure 12 shows the main mobility results of the paper. I find that workers in highly disrupted
regions are more likely to switch both industries and commuting zones in response to training. Workers
are approximately 20 percentage points more likely to move commuting zones and 28 percentage points
more likely to switch industries (at the 2-digit North American Industrial Classification System (NAICS)
level), with respect to the location and industry of their pre-layoff employer. These are large effects,
when compared with baseline mobility rates of 0.26 and 0.23 for commuting zones and 2-digit industries
respectively (subtracting baseline estimates in Table 3 from 1.)
58
While not as well identified due to potential selection concerns (but nonetheless supported by
common pre-trends), I also present suggestive evidence that positive earnings returns among “movers”
drive the overall effects relative to “stayers”. I define movers and stayers by their ex-post mobility
decisions, which may reflect a self-selected sample that differs along a number of unobservables. Figure
13 shows that the main earnings results of the paper map very closely to effects for movers.
59
Overall, while there is suggestive evidence that TAA-trained workers previously were bound by
adjustment frictions, the analyses above are not explicit tests for externalities. Whether TAA is effectively
expanding a feasible match radius or alleviating an informational friction remains prime ground for
future study.
60
If in fact these workers are facing trade shocks which are spatially correlated (and
industrially concentrated if sufficiently agglomerated in those regions), this might also explain why
earnings returns are especially strong among movers. These workers would need to have much larger
search radii to find productive employment.
61
Whether these strong mobility responses reflect matching
or information frictions, liquidity constraints (Chetty, 2008), or both, also remains to be tested.
6 Cost Effectiveness
While the paper’s identification strategy provides robust evidence of positive earnings returns and
higher mobility associated with TAA, this does not inform us about the social cost-effectiveness of the
program. Toward this second end, I compare the ten year stream of estimated TAA earnings returns as
benefits, with average TAA expenditures on training, extended UI, and foregone earnings while training,
as costs.
62
I incorporate two important potential sources of deadweight loss (DWL): the excess burden
58
Results for low-shock regions are shown in Results for low-shock regions can be found in Appendix B.8.
59
By contrast, Figure B.6 shows the effects for stayers, which I interpret as those who by chance happen to get the remaining
jobs open in their local economies.
60
See Shimer (2007) for a framework analyzing the roles of search and skill mismatch frictions in unemployment.
61
In ongoing work, I am investigating this further by taking advantage of distances moved between employers.
62
For an alternative welfare analysis, Hendren (2016) proposes a “Marginal Value of Public Funds” approach which is
arguably more comparable across programs. I provide results using this approach in Appendix A.3.
27
from taxation (“leakage”from redistribution), and moral hazard search costs associated with extended
unemployment insurance transfers. These are incorporated as follows:
Benefits =
Earnings Returns from TAA
z }| {
τ=10
τ=2
ˆ
β
τ
(1 + r)
τ+1
(8)
Costs =
τ=1
τ=0
Foregone Earnings + Training Costs (& DWL)
z }| {
ˆ
β
τ
+ (1 + e)Training +
UI Transfer Costs (Moral Hazard & DWL)
z }| {
( e + ) UI
(1 + r)
τ+1
(9)
Here, Benefits are the discounted stream of relative TAA earnings returns for post-training years (τ =
2...10), with
ˆ
β
τ
parameter estimates taken from Appendix C.1.
63
Costs contain two main terms. The
first term is the discounted sum of foregone earnings while training (
ˆ
β
τ
< 0 for τ [0, 1]) and average
expenditures on training, where Training = $6, 181.96 is calculated from the data shown in Appendix
B.5. e represents the excess burden required by taxation to finance each dollar spent on training (Okun’s
“leaky bucket”).
64
The second term is simpler because UI transfers from one agent to another only
implicate social costs through excess burden (e [0, 1]) and search disincentives induced by the transfer
scheme ( [0, 1]).
65
To simplify the analysis, I set = 0.345 (=0.6/1.6 following Schmieder and Von Wachter (2016)).
Setting UI = $13, 181.96, again taken from Appendix B.5, we then solve the internal rate of return r that
equates net present benefits to costs for different values of e. Following Heckman et al. (2010), I show
both private and societal internal rates of return to TAA for a range of excess burden values (where
private returns to workers only include foregone earnings costs associated with training.)
Internal Rate of Return to TAA
Leakage Parameter (e) Private Return Social Return
0% 49.5% 17.0%
25% 49.5% 9.1%
50% 49.5% 4.0%
75% 49.5% 0%
100% 49.5% -3.0%
63
Note that τ + 1 is in the exponent of the discount term to be consistent with prior notation. τ = 0 should be thought of as
year one, such that the social planner is positioned at τ = 1 when calculating the IRR.
64
This first term reflects the opportunity cost of training resources which could otherwise be allocated to other activities.
65
That is, instead of including as costs (1 + e + ) multiplied by each annual UI value, UI could easily be incorporated into
benefits which cancels out the ”1”. We thus only need to concern ourselves with dead-weight loss and distortion parameters.
28
Note: Private returns assume workers do not bear any of the incidence of any Ricardian effects induced by the excess burden
of taxation, hence their stability across different deadweight loss parameter values.
I estimate an internal rate of return (IRR) on TAA of between 0.0% and 9.1% for deadweight loss
values ranging between 0.25 and 0.75. I interpret this as a lower bound for at least two reasons. First,
earnings returns are calculated from an intent-to-treat (ITT) estimator which likely understates benefits
due to imperfect compliance with the treatment (i.e. partial take-up of TAA attenuates earnings estimates
toward zero). Second, TAA may induce worker substitution away from other costly social insurance
programs such as disability insurance (DI), which would further decrease program costs.
66
One important caveat to the above calculations however, is that positive earnings returns are
estimated from a local average treatment effect (LATE) that does not capture the fact that firms may
be incentivized to lay off additional workers after learning of their TAA eligibility status. Nevertheless,
back-of-the-envelope calculations show that these are unlikely to outweigh potentially much larger
downward pressures. Finally, it bears noting that like other public programs, the additional public
revenue from taxation of increased earnings returns for TAA takers is not sufficient to cover program
costs.
7 Concluding Remarks
One of the most prominent challenges facing low-income workers in a modern, global labor market,
is how labor will adjust to a rapidly changing and increasingly automated economy. Trade-impacted
workers have received a large share of this attention, which became particularly visible as a policy issue
during the 2016 Presidential Election. While low-income households have benefited tremendously from
trade in terms of lower costs of goods, higher variety, and quality of life improvements associated with
technological advancement, recent evidence suggests that they have also been persistently negatively
affected in terms of earnings and employment outcomes. Despite growing evidence that trade’s
disperse benefits also come with concentrated costs, little is known about policy efforts that deliberately
target the adjustment process for those most affected by regionally and industrially shocked labor
markets. Credible empirical estimates are made difficult by both a lack of detailed worker-level data
and confounding factors correlated with qualifying for adjustment programs—selection biases which
generally preclude reliable estimates.
This paper estimates the causal effects of Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA)—the United States’
largest and longest standing public incentive program for retraining—on worker outcomes, by
leveraging quasi-random assignment of TAA cases to investigators of varying approval leniencies. Using
66
Autor et al. (2014) find that DI is in fact the predominant margin through which workers adjust to trade shocks.
29
employer-employee matched Census data on 300,000 displaced workers, the paper provides evidence
of large initial returns to TAA. Workers inferred to take up benefits forego roughly $10,000 in income
while training, yet ten years later have approximately $50,000 higher cumulative earnings relative to
all-else-equal workers that do not retrain. I estimate that 33% of these returns are driven by higher
wages—a sizable share which suggests that TAA-trained workers are not only compensated through
greater labor force participation or higher priority in job queues. Rather, TAA workers also appear to be
paid a premium for their newly acquired human capital. But these large relative gains also decay over
time, such that annual incomes among TAA and non-TAA workers fully converge after ten years. In
conjunction with two additional pieces of evidence—that TAA has no effect on formal education, and
diminishing returns are restricted to states with low training durations—I attribute this depreciation to
short-run demanded skills becoming obsolete (consistent with rapid skill-biased technological change
or an overall declining labor share). Indeed, 62% of TAA training programs confer vocational degrees
with shorter program lengths than typical community college or 4-year college degrees which have been
shown to have durable earnings returns.
In the most disrupted regions, workers are more likely to switch industries and move to labor
markets with better opportunities in response to TAA, suggesting a potentially important role for
human capital in overcoming adjustment frictions. However, one limitation to the study is that I do not
identify whether TAA is effectively expanding a feasible job match radius for its participants, or instead
alleviating other frictions, which may include worker present-bias, household liquidity constraints, and
other hypotheses. If in fact these workers are facing trade shocks which are spatially correlated (and
industrially concentrated if sufficiently agglomerated in those regions), this might also explain why
earnings returns are especially strong among movers.
Lastly, a cost-benefit analysis produces a conservative internal rate of return (IRR) on TAA between
0.0% and 9.1%. Despite this being a relatively low IRR, policymakers may still consider the efficiency
costs associated with TAA investments a worthwhile trade-off as a redistributive policy toward this
sub-population. This would be especially true if there were either other externalities associated with
TAA training, or current social insurance programs were shown to be insufficient for these workers.
One outstanding and related puzzle is if labor markets signal high private returns to human capital
investments such as TAA training, and this study confirms those high returns, then why are take-up
rates so persistently low? Future work will need to explain this puzzle, and further examine whether
the results from this paper are relevant to other types of labor market pressures such as automation.
30
References
Abowd, J. M., Stephens, B. E., Vilhuber, L., Andersson, F., McKinney, K. L., Roemer, M., and
Woodcock, S. The LEHD infrastructure files and the creation of the Quarterly Workforce Indicators. In
Producer dynamics: New evidence from micro data (pp. 149-230). 2009. University of Chicago Press.
Acemoglu, Daron, and David Autor. ”Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Implications for Employment and
Earnings.” Handbook of Labor Economics 4 (2011): 1043-1171.
Ackerberg, Daniel A., and Paul J. Devereux. ”Improved JIVE Estimators for Overidentified Linear
Models with and without Heteroskedasticity.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 91.2 (2009):
351-362.
Aghion, P., Angeletos, M., Banerjee, A., and Kalina, B. K. Manova (2005),“Volatility and Growth: Credit
Constraints and Productivity-Enhancing Investment”. NBER Working Paper, (11349).
Amiti, Mary, and Donald R. Davis. ”Trade, Firms, and Wages: Theory and evidence.” The Review of
economic studies 79.1 (2011): 1-36.
Angrist, Joshua D., and Alan B. Krueger. ”Split-sample instrumental variables estimates of the return
to schooling.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 13.2 (1995): 225-235.
Angrist, Joshua David, Guido W. Imbens, and Alan B. Krueger. ”Jackknife instrumental variables
estimation.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 14.1 (1999): 57-67.
Ashenfelter, Orley. ”Estimating the effect of training programs on earnings.” The Review of Economics
and Statistics (1978): 47-57.
Ashenfelter, Orley C., and David Card. “Using the longitudinal structure of earnings to estimate the
effect of training programs.” The Review of Economics and Statistics (1985): 648-660.
Augenblick, Ned, Muriel Niederle, and Charles Sprenger. (2015) ”Working over time: Dynamic
inconsistency in real effort tasks.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 130.3 : 1067-1115.
Autor, D., Dorn, D., Katz, L. F., Patterson, C., and Van Reenen, J. (2017). “The Fall of the Labor Share
and the Rise of Superstar Firms” (No. dp1482). Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.
Autor, David H., Dorn, D., Hanson, Gordon H.., and Majlesi, K. (2016). Importing Political
Polarization? Massachusetts Institute of Technology Manuscript.
31
Autor, David H., Dorn, David, and Hanson, Gordon H. ”The China Shock: Learning from labor-market
adjustment to large changes in trade.” Annual Review of Economics, 2016, 8: 205-240.
Autor, David H., Dorn, David, Hanson, Gordon H., and Song, Jae ”Trade Adjustment: Worker-level
Evidence.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2014, 129, no. 4: 1799-1860.
Autor, David H., and Dorn, David. The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the US
Labor Market.” The American Economic Review 2013a, 103.5: 1553-1597.
Autor, David H., Dorn, David, and Hanson, Gordon H. ”The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market
Effects of Import Competition in the United States.” The American Economic Review, 2013, 103.6:.
2121-2168.
Autor, David, Andreas Ravndal Kostol, and Magne Mogstad. ”Disability Benefits, Consumption
Insurance, and Household Labor Supply.” 2015.
Bartik, Alexander W. ”Worker Adjustment to Changes in Labor Demand: Evidence from Longitudinal
Census Data.” Job Market Paper, 2017.
Becker, Gary. ”Human capital revisited.” Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with
Special Reference to Education (3rd Edition). The University of Chicago Press, 1994. 15-28.
Belloni, A., Chen, D., Chernozhukov, V., Hansen, C. (2012). “Sparse models and methods for optimal
instruments with an application to eminent domain.” Econometrica, 80(6), 2369-2429.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean, Lawrence F. Katz, in Robert E. Hall, and Barry Eichengreen. ”Regional
Evolutions.” Brookings papers on economic activity. 1992, no. 1: 1-75.
Blinder, Alan S. ”How many US jobs might be offshorable?.” World Economics 10.2 (2009): 41. (Originally
cited as 2007 working paper.)
Bureau of Labor Statistics (FRED). All Employees: Manufacturing [MANEMP] and Nonfarm Business
Sector: Real Output [OUTNFB], retrieved from FRED 2017, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis;
https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/MANEMP and https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/OUTNFB
Card, David. ”Estimating the Return to schooling: Progress on Some Persistent Econometric Problems.”
Econometrica 69.5 (2001): 1127-1160.
Card, David, Jochen Kluve, and Andrea Weber. “Active Labour Market Policy Evaluations: A
meta-analysis.” The Economic Journal 120.548 (2010).
32
Chetty, Raj. ”Moral hazard versus liquidity and optimal unemployment insurance.” Journal of political
Economy 116.2 (2008): 173-234.
Colas, Mark. ”Dynamic Responses to Immigration.” 2016. Job Market Paper. University of
Wisconsin-Madison.
Council of Economic Advisers ”Artificial Intelligence, Automation, and the Economy” Executive Office
of the President, December 2016.
Dehejia, Rajeev H., and Sadek Wahba. ”Causal effects in nonexperimental studies: Reevaluating the
evaluation of training programs.” Journal of the American statistical Association 94.448 (1999): 1053-1062.
Dixit, Avinash, and Victor Norman. ”Gains from Trade without Lump-Sum Compensation.” Journal of
International Economics 21.1-2 (1986): 111-122.
Dix-Carneiro, Rafael, and Brian K. Kovak. “Margins of labor market adjustment to trade.” No. w23595.
National Bureau of Economic Research, 2017.
Dobbie, Will, and Song, Jae. ”Debt Relief and Debtor Outcomes: Measuring the Effects of Consumer
Bankruptcy Protection.” The American Economic Review 2015, 105.3: 1272-1311.
Dorn, David ”Essays on Inequality, Spatial Interaction, and the Demand for Skills.” Dissertation
University of St. Gallen no. 3613, September 2009.
Doyle Jr, Joseph J. ”Child protection and adult crime: Using investigator assignment to estimate causal
effects of foster care.” Journal of Political Economy 116.4 (2008): 746-770.
Ebenstein, A., Harrison, A., McMillan, M., and Phillips, S. (2014). Estimating the Impact of Trade
and Offshoring on American Workers using the Current Population Surveys. Review of Economics and
Statistics, 96(4), 581-595.
Fajgelbaum, Pablo D., and Amit K. Khandelwal. ”Measuring the Unequal Gains from Trade.” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 131.3 (2016): 1113-1180.
Feenstra, Robert C., and Tracy R. Lewis (1994). ”Trade Adjustment Assistance and Pareto Gains from
Trade.” Journal of International Economics, 1994, 36.3: 201-222.
Feenstra, R., Hong Ma, and Yuan Xu. ”US Exports and Employment.” University of California, Davis
and Tsinghua University, Beijing (2017). (2017)
33
Feenstra, Robert C., and Akira Sasahara. ”The ’China Shock’, Exports and US Employment.” Working
Paper (2017).
Firpo, Sergio, Nicole Fortin, and Thomas Lemieux. ”Occupational tasks and changes in the wage
structure.” (2011).
Flaaen, Aaron, Matthew D. Shapiro, and Isaac Sorkin. ”Reconsidering the Consequences of Worker
Displacements: Survey versus Administrative Measurements. 2016.”
Goldin, Claudia Dale, and Lawrence F. Katz. The Race Between Education and Technology. Harvard
University Press, 2009.
Harrison, Ann, and McMillan, Margaret ”Offshoring Jobs? Multinationals and U.S. Manufacturing
Employment” The Review of Economics and Statistics. 2011 93:3, 857-875
Heckman, James J. ”The common structure of statistical models of truncation, sample selection and
limited dependent variables and a simple estimator for such models.” Annals of Economic and Social
Measurement, Volume 5, number 4. NBER, 1976. 475-492.
Heckman, James J., Hidehiko Ichimura, Jeffrey Smith, and Petra Todd. ”Sources of selection bias
in evaluating social programs: An interpretation of conventional measures and evidence on the
effectiveness of matching as a program evaluation method.” Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences 93, no. 23 (1996): 13416-13420.
Heckman, J. J., Ichimura, H., and Todd, P. E. (1997). Matching as an econometric evaluation estimator:
Evidence from evaluating a job training programme. The Review of Economic Studies, 64(4), 605-654.
Heckman, James J., Robert J. LaLonde, and Jeffrey A. Smith. ”The Economics and Econometrics of
Active Labor Market Programs.” Handbook of Labor Economics 3 (1999): 1865-2097.
Heckman, James J., Jora Stixrud, and Sergio Urzua. ”The effects of cognitive and noncognitive abilities
on labor market outcomes and social behavior.” Journal of Labor economics 24.3 (2006): 411-482.
Heckman, J. J., Moon, S. H., Pinto, R., Savelyev, P., Yavitz, A. (2010). A new cost-benefit and rate
of return analysis for the Perry Preschool Program: A summary (No. w16180). National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Hendren, Nathaniel. ”The policy elasticity.” Tax Policy and the Economy 30.1 (2016): 51-89.
Hicks, John ”The Foundations of Welfare Economics.” The Economic Journal. 1939. 49.196: 696-712
34
Imbens, Guido W., and Joshua D. Angrist. ”Identification and Estimation of Local Average Treatment
Effects.” Econometrica (1986-1998) 62.2 (1994): 467.
Kaldor, Nicholas ”Welfare propositions and interpersonal comparisons of utility.” The Economic Journal.
1939, 549-552.
Kane, Thomas J., and Cecilia Elena Rouse. ”Labor-giket returns to two-and four-year college.” The
American Economic Review 85.3 (1995): 600-614.
Kletzer, Lori G. ”Trade-related Job Loss and Wage Insurance: a Synthetic Review.” Review of International
Economics 12.5 (2004): 724-748.
Kling, Jeffrey R. ”Incarceration Length, Employment, and Earnings.” The American Economic Review,
2006, 96.3:863-876.
Kline, Patrick, and Enrico Moretti. ”Local Economic Development, Agglomeration Economies, and
the Big Push: 100 Years of Evidence from the Tennessee Valley Authority.” The Quarterly Journal of
Economics 129.1 (2013): 275-331.
Kline, Patrick, and Enrico Moretti. ”People, Places, and Public Policy: Some Simple Welfare Economics
of Local Economic Development Programs.” (2014). Annual Review of Economics Vol. 6:629-662.
Kolesar, Michal. ”Estimation in an instrumental variables model with treatment effect heterogeneity.”
Unpublished Working Paper (2013).
Kondo, Illenin, Trade Reforms, Foreign Competition, and Labor Market Adjustments in the U.S.
(December 31, 2013). FRB International Finance Discussion Paper No. 1095.
Kovak, Brian K., Lindsay Oldenski, and Nicholas Sly. The labor market effects of offshoring by us
multinational firms: Evidence from changes in global tax policies. No. w23947. National Bureau of
Economic Research, 2017.
Lachowska, Marta, Alexandre Mas, and Stephen A. Woodbury. ”Sources of Displaced Workers’
Long-Term Earnings Losses.” 2017, working paper.
LaLonde, Robert J. ”Evaluating the econometric evaluations of training programs with experimental
data.” The American economic review (1986): 604-620. APA
Lochner, Lance J., and Alexander Monge-Naranjo. ”The nature of credit constraints and human
capital.” The American Economic Review 101.6 (2011): 2487-2529.
35
Lyon, Spencer, and Waugh, Michael. “Redistributing the Gains From Trade through Progressive
Taxation”. Working paper, New York University.
Mian, Atif, and Amir Sufi. ”What explains the 2007–2009 drop in employment?.” Econometrica 82.6
(2014): 2197-2223. APA
Monarch, Ryan, Park, Jooyoun, Sivadasan, Jagadeesh, ”Domestic Gains from Offshoring? Evidence
from TAA-linked U.S. Microdata” Journal of International Economics. March, 2017, Vol 105, pp.150-173.
Mortensen, Dale, and Pissarides, Christopher. ”Job creation and job destruction in the theory of
unemployment.” The Review of Economic Studies, 1994, 61.3: 397-415.
Mueller-Smith, Michael. (2015) ”The Criminal and Labor Market Impacts of Incarceration.” 2015, Job
Market Paper.)
Pierce, Justin R., and Peter K. Schott. ”The surprisingly swift decline of US manufacturing
employment.” The American Economic Review 106.7 (2016): 1632-1662.
Ryan, Camille L., and Julie Siebens. ”Educational Attainment in the United States: 2009. Population
Characteristics. Current Population Reports. P20-566.” US Census Bureau (2012).
Schochet, P. Z., D’Amico, R., Berk, J., Dolfin, S., and Wozny, N. (2012). “Estimated Impacts for
Participants in the Trade Adjustment Assistance TAA Program Under the 2002 Amendments” (No.
582d8723f6884d4eb7a3f95a4d5ef086). Mathematica Policy Research.
Schmieder, Johannes F., Till Von Wachter, and Stefan Bender. ”The effects of extended unemployment
insurance over the business cycle: Evidence from regression discontinuity estimates over 20 years.”
The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127.2 (2012): 701-752.
Schmieder, Johannes F., Till Von Wachter. ”The effects of unemployment insurance benefits: New
evidence and interpretation.” Annual Review of Economics 8 (2016): 547-581.
Serrato, Juan Carlos Su´arez, and Owen Zidar. ”Who benefits from state corporate tax cuts? A local labor
markets approach with heterogeneous firms.” The American Economic Review 106.9 (2016): 2582-2624.
Shimer, Robert. ”Mismatch.” American Economic Review 97.4 (2007): 1074-1101.
Smith, Jeffrey A., and Petra E. Todd. ”Reconciling conflicting evidence on the performance of
propensity-score matching methods.” The American Economic Review 91.2 (2001): 112-118.
Todd, Petra E. ”Matching estimators.” Microeconometrics. Palgrave Macmillan UK, 2010. 108-121. APA
36
Vilhuber, Lars, and Kevin McKinney. LEHD Infrastructure files in the Census RDC-Overview. No.
14-26. 2014.
Von Wachter, Till, Jae Song, and Joyce Manchester “Long-term earnings losses due to mass layoffs
during the 1982 recession: An analysis using US administrative data from 1974 to 2004.” Unpublished
paper, Columbia University.
Yagan, Danny. ”Moving to opportunity? Migratory insurance over the Great Recession.” Job Market
Paper (2014). (Later version appears in 2016 Journal of Political Economy)
37
Figure 1. Manufacturing Employment and Real Output
NOTES—This figure shows seasonally adjusted data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), retrieved from
FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The solid line plots monthly US workers employed in manufacturing
industries (BLS Current Employment Statistics, CES3000000001). The dashed line shows a quarterly index of
nonfarm business sector real output (BLS Labor productivity and Costs) where 2009q1=100. In a similar figure,
Pierce and Schott (2016) show the upward pattern in output persists for manufacturing sector value added, which
suggests falling labor intensity drives the decline rather than secular stagnation. Source: BLS (2017)
Figure 2. TAA Filer Time Series (USDOL Estimates)
NOTES—This figure shows the estimated number of workers eligible for TAA benefits as covered by petitions at
the Department of Labor. Worker estimates are generated by case investigators processing plant-level information
(at times acquired using subpoena power), and cover the entire 3-year eligibility window shown in the timeline in
Section 2. Recession quarters are indicated in gray, and taken from NBER Business Cycle Dating Committee data.
The final matched analysis sample studies petitions filed between 1990 and 2011 for a subset of 23 approved states
(see text for further details). Source: USDOL (OTAA) petition database attained via FOIA request; NBER Business
Cycle Dating Committee
38
Figure 3. Workers Filing for TAA: All (Top) versus LEHD Sample (Bottom)
NOTES—These maps show the cumulative number of TAA filers by 1990 commuting zone (geographies taken
from Dorn (2009)). The top sample reflects the universe of TAA filers from 1974 to 2016. The bottom sample
displays all filers in 24 LEHD-approved states from 1990 to 2011, forming the basis of the matched analysis sample.
Both maps display cumulative numbers by quintile. See Appendix B.7 for a population-weighted version of the
same maps. Source: USDOL (OTAA) petition database attained via FOIA request
39
Figure 4. Displaced Worker Earnings, naive Difference-in-Differences (Top)
versus Leniency IV “Reduced Form” (Bottom)
NOTES—These plots show locally smoothed polynomial regressions of annual earnings before and after worker
separation. Unconditional (top) and residualized (bottom) means are estimated for the main analysis sample:
working-age individuals (22-65) with 2 years of positive earnings above the annual minimum wage equivalent
prior to filing ($7.25 * 2,082 average working hours in 2010 $15,000), earning less than $50,000 annually in the
pre-period. Monetary variables are deflated to 2010 US dollars, seasonally adjusted, and winsorized at 1% to limit
outliers. Leniency quartiles (bottom panel) are calculated across 250 investigators. Source: LEHD; USDOL
40
Figure 5. Leniency IV versus Investigator Caseload and Tenure
NOTES—These plots show the relationship between the main leave-one-out investigator leniency measure and:
(1) investigator caseload measured by number of petitions (top); (2) investigator tenure in total years (bottom).
Leniency, caseload, and tenure, are first regressed on year-of-filing fixed effects. Residuals from these regressions
are then averaged across 100 quantile bins and plotted across the support of the x-axis variable. Residualized
values are added to the overall mean leniency rate for ease of interpretation. Source: USDOL historical employee
records acquired via FOIA request
41
Figure 6. Variation in TAA Investigator Leniency
NOTES—This figure plots the number of petitions filed across bins of residualized leave-one-out investigator
leniency (see text for details), from the final matched LEHD sample (kernel bandwidth and 5% tails withheld
for confidentiality). The top plot is overlaid with a local linear regression of approval rates on residualized
leniency, meant to demonstrate the first stage. The bottom panel shows the difference between residuaized and
unresidualized leniency measures. Source: USDOL historical employee records acquired via FOIA request, LEHD
42
Figure 7. Dynamic Effects of TAA on Worker Earnings
NOTES—These plots show the main 2SLS coefficient estimates of the effects of TAA on annual earnings (top) and
within-worker cumulative earnings (bottom), dynamically across event years relative to the TAA petition decision
(τ = 0). Each point estimate is from a separate cross-sectional regression by event year. Cumulative earnings
are summed from τ = 10 to the event year on the x-axis. Vertical lines partition the support into pre-TAA,
during-TAA, and post-TAA periods. Sample restrictions and variable definitions are identical to those described
in Table 5, column 6 (the paper’s preferred earnings specification). Dotted lines represent 90% confidence intervals
with standard errors clustered at the investigator level. Source: LEHD; USDOL
43
Figure 8. Dynamic Effects of TAA on Labor Force Participation
NOTES—These plots show the main 2SLS coefficient estimates of the effects of TAA on quarters employed (top)
and number of jobs held (bottom), dynamically across event years relative to the TAA petition decision (τ = 0).
Each point estimate is from a separate cross-sectional regression by event year. Baseline quarters employed and
number of jobs held are 3.56 and 1.11 respectively (Table 3, column 1). Vertical lines partition the support into
pre-TAA, during-TAA, and post-TAA periods. Sample restrictions and variable definitions are identical to those
described in Table 6, column 6 (the paper’s preferred employment specification). Dotted lines represent 90%
confidence intervals with standard errors clustered at the investigator level. Source: LEHD; USDOL
44
Figure 9. Dynamic Effects of TAA on Formal Education
Prob(Education High School Degree)
Prob(Education Some College)
NOTES—These plots show the main 2SLS coefficient estimates of the effects of TAA on formal education take-up
using both imputed and non-imputed decennial census measures which are merged to the Census LEHD (see text
for details), dynamically across all event years relative to the TAA petition decision (τ = 0). Each point estimate
is from a separate cross-sectional regression by event year. Education can take four ordinal values: 1=Some
High School; 2=High School Degree; 3=Some College; 4=College Degree. Vertical lines partition the pre-TAA,
during-TAA, and post-TAA periods. Sample restrictions and variable definitions are identical to those described in
Table 7, column 5 (the paper’s preferred education specification). Dotted lines represent 90% confidence intervals
with standard errors clustered at the investigator level. Source: LEHD; USDOL
45
Figure 10. Heterogeneous Earnings Effects of TAA by State Training Duration
NOTES—This figure overlays two series of 2SLS estimates, corresponding to each β
1τ
and β
2τ
of equation (5) of
the draft where coefficients reflect high and low training duration lengths. Each point estimate is from a separate
regression by event year, showing the effects of TAA on worker earnings interacted with high and low training
duration in the state and quarter in which the worker was laid off (pre-period). “High” and “Low” are defined
relative to median training duration, which is calculated for each quarter across states using TAA performance
data from 2001 to 2016 (training duration data are not available prior to 2001). Vertical lines partition the pre-TAA,
during-TAA, and post-TAA periods. Besides the sub-sample from data limitations, remaining sample restrictions
and variable definitions are identical to those described in Table 6, column 5. Standard errors are suppressed
for exposition (see online appendix for underlying data and standard errors). Source: LEHD; USDOL Trade Act
Participant Report (TAPR), 2001 to 2016
46
Figure 11. Heterogeneous Earnings Effects of TAA by Labor Market Strength
NOTES—This figure shows two series of 2SLS estimates, corresponding to each β
1τ
and β
2τ
of equation (5) of the
draft. Coefficients reflect workers displaced in high (top) and low (bottom) initial unemployment rate regions.
Each point estimate is from a separate regression by event year, showing the effects of TAA on worker earnings
by high and low training duration in the state and year in which the worker was laid off. “High” and “Low”
are defined relative to median training duration, which is calculated for each quarter across states using TAA
performance data from 2001 to 2016 (training duration data are not available prior to 2001). Vertical lines partition
the pre-TAA, during-TAA, and post-TAA periods. Besides the data constraint from limited performance data,
sample restrictions and variable definitions are identical to those described in Table 5, column 6. Dotted lines
represent 90% confidence intervals with standard errors clustered at the investigator level. Source: LEHD; BLS
Local Area Unemployment Statistics (LAUS)
47
Figure 12. Effects of TAA on Worker Mobility by Initial Labor Market Strength
NOTES—This figure shows two series of 2SLS estimates, corresponding to each β
1τ
and of equation (5) of the draft
where the dependent variables are the probability that a worker is employed in the same commuting zone (top)
and 2-digit NAICS industry (bottom) as the region and industry from which they initially separated. Estimates
are broken out for high shock unemployment regions, where each point estimate is from a separate regression
by event year. Commuting zones are defined by 1990 boundaries originally geocoded by Dorn (2009). Baseline
mobility rates are 0.26 and 0.23 for commuting zones and 2-digit industries respectively, taken by subtracting the
values found in Table 3, column 1 from 1. Vertical lines partition the pre-TAA, during-TAA, and post-TAA periods.
Sample restrictions and variable definitions are identical to those described in Table 6, column 6. Source: LEHD;
USDOL; BLS Local Area Unemployment Statistics (LAUS)
48
Figure 13. Earnings Effects of TAA for Labor Market and Industry “Movers”
NOTES—This figure shows 2SLS estimates of the effects of TAA for workers who move commuting zones (top)
or switch 2-digit NAICS industries (bottom) in the post-period, relative to the region and industry in which they
were initially employed. This ex-post definition of mobility is used as a subgroup in a specification similar to
equation (5) of the draft, where only coefficients on movers are plotted here (see Appendix B.6 for analogous
results for “stayers”). Movers comprise approximately 47% and 56% of the sample for commuting zones and
industries respectively. Each point estimate is from a separate regression by event year. Vertical lines partition the
pre-TAA, during-TAA, and post-TAA periods. Sample restrictions and variable definitions are identical to those
described in Table 5, column 6. Dotted lines represent 90% confidence intervals with standard errors clustered at
the investigator level. Results for low-shock regions can be found in Appendix B.8. Source: LEHD; USDOL
49
Table 1. Location of Top 10 “Trade Displaced” TAA Zip Codes
Rank 1975-1985 1985-1995 1995-2005 2005-2016
1. Flint, MI Seattle, WA Los Angeles, CA Fremont, CA
2. Detroit, MI (a) Fort Worth, TX Seattle, WA Detroit, MI
3. Detroit, MI (b) Houston, TX (a) East Chicago, IN Nashville, TN
4. Detroit, MI (c) Linden, NJ Long Beach, CA St. Louis, MI
5. Detroit, MI (d) Flint, MI San Jose, CA Wichita, KS
6. Detroit, MI (e) Los Angeles, CA Scranton, PA Dayton, OH
7. Saginaw, MI Houston, TX (b) Washington, NC Warren, OH
8. Dayton, OH Milwaukee, WI New York, NY Wilmington, OH
9. Kokomo, IN Toledo, OH Dallas, TX Los Angeles, CA
10. Ann Arbor, MI Framingham, MA Seattle, WA Detroit, MI
Affected
Industries
(Mode)
Motor Vehicles,
Parts, Accessories
Oil & Gas Extract.,
Exploration,
Services
Electronics,
Aircraft, Textiles
Auto Parts, Plastics
Aircraft, Computers
Pharmaceuticals
NOTES—This table reports the locations of the top ten “trade-displaced” zip codes as calculated from Department
of Labor estimates of the total number of workers eligible for TAA, as associated with filed TAA petitions at the
plant level. The reported industry reflects the qualitative description associated with the top three to five modal
industries in the same decade using standard industrial classification (SIC) codes ascribed to petitions by case
investigators. Source: USDOL (OTAA) petition database attained via FOIA request
50
Table 2. Descriptive Statistics for TAA Approved and Denied Workers
High Labor Force Attachment High & Low Labor Force Attachment
TAA Approved TAA Denied All TAA Approved TAA Denied All
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
A. Worker Demographics (LEHD)
Age (time of filing) 43.91 (10.93) 43.08 (11.09) 43.65 (10.99) 42.7 (11.13) 41.76 (11.16) 42.41 (11.15)
Female 0.54 (0.50) 0.50 (0.50) 0.53 (0.50) 0.56 (0.50) 0.52 (0.50) 0.55 (0.50)
Black 0.11 (0.32) 0.13 (0.33) 0.12 (0.32) 0.13 (0.33) 0.15 (0.35) 0.13 (0.34)
White 0.80 (0.40) 0.79 (0.40) 0.80 (0.40) 0.79 (0.41) 0.78 (0.42) 0.78 (0.41)
High School Degree 0.39 (0.49) 0.37 (0.48) 0.39 (0.49) 0.38 (0.49) 0.37 (0.48) 0.37 (0.48)
Some College 0.29 (0.45) 0.31 (0.46) 0.30 (0.46) 0.29 (0.45) 0.31 (0.46) 0.29 (0.45)
College Degree and Above 0.11 (0.31) 0.14 (0.35) 0.12 (0.33) 0.12 (0.32) 0.14 (0.35) 0.13 (0.33)
B. Worker Economic Variables (LEHD)
Annual Earnings ($1,000) 22.554 (13.511) 23.468 (14.793) 22.83 (13.916) 18.628 (13.904) 19.232 (15.136) 18.814 (14.294)
Quarters Employed 3.21 (1.28) 3.14 (1.33) 3.19 (1.30) 2.93 (1.42) 2.87 (1.47) 2.92 (1.44)
Quarters Employed (full-time equivalence) 2.77 (1.54) 2.71 (1.57) 2.75 (1.55) 2.28 (1.67) 2.22 (1.70) 2.26 (1.68)
Employed 0.79 (0.40) 0.76 (0.43) 0.78 (0.41) 0.74 (0.44) 0.7 (0.46) 0.73 (0.45)
# of Jobs / Year 0.95 (0.75) 0.92 (0.78) 0.94 (0.76) 0.94 (0.08) 0.91 (0.85) 0.93 (0.84)
Tenure (years at separation) 4.90 (3.71) 3.87 (3.24) 4.58 (3.60) 14.76 (14.52) 11.5 (12.29) 13.74 (13.94)
Init. Employer Mean Earnings ($1,000) 23.197 (5.628) 23.216 (5.596) 23.204 (5.617) 20.822 (6.59) 21.100 (6.338) 20.910 (6.513)
County Unemployment Rate (time of filing) 6.51 (2.28) 6.4 (1.85) 6.48 (2.16) 6.43 (2.20) 6.40 (1.78) 6.42 (2.08)
Prob(Employed at Petitioner Firm) 0.66 (0.47) 0.66 (0.47) 0.66 (0.47) 0.63 (0.48) 0.64 (0.48) 0.63 (0.48)
Prob(Employed at Petitioner 2-Digit NAICS) 0.7 (0.46) 0.71 (0.45) 0.70 (0.46) 0.68 (0.47) 0.69 (0.46) 0.68 (0.47)
Prob(Employed in Petitioner Commuting Zone) 0.69 (0.46) 0.72 (0.45) 0.70 (0.46) 0.67 (0.47) 0.72 (0.45) 0.69 (0.46)
C. Petitioner Characteristics (DOL)
Company Filer 0.40 (0.49) 0.10 (0.3) 0.31 (0.46) 0.40 (0.49) 0.11 (0.31) 0.31 (0.46)
Union Filer 0.14 (0.34) 0.19 (0.39) 0.15 (0.36) 0.13 (0.34) 0.17 (0.38) 0.14 (0.35)
Worker-Group Filer 0.37 (0.48) 0.63 (0.48) 0.45 (0.50) 0.37 (0.48) 0.65 (0.48) 0.46 (0.50)
Investigator Caseload (no. of petitions) 22.83 (18.25) 22.27 (16.21) 22.66 (17.64) 23.05 (18.68) 22.44 (16.35) 22.86 (17.99)
Investigator Tenure (decades) 0.979 (0.942) 1.02 (0.879) 0.991 (0.925) 1.02 (0.950) 0.995 (0.872) 1.01 (0.928)
Prob(Tradable) (Mian & Sufi, 2011) 0.64 (0.48) 0.51 (0.50) 0.60 (0.49) 0.58 (0.49) 0.43 (0.50) 0.53 (0.50)
Offshorability Z-Score (Blinder, 2007) 0.29 (0.84) 0.09 (1.23) 0.22 (0.98) 0.25 (0.87) 0.02 (1.28) 0.18 (1.02)
Offshorability Z-Score (Autor & Dorn, 2013) 0.23 (0.86) 0.27 (0.79) 0.24 (0.84) 0.16 (0.84) 0.22 (0.78) 0.17 (0.82)
Number of Petitioners 3,100 1,300 4,300 3,300 1,400 4,700
Number of Displaced Workers 123,000 54,000 177,000 198,000 89,000 287,000
Number of Observations 1,811,000 810,000 2,623,000 2,883,000 1,307,000 4,192,000
NOTES—This table reports means and standard deviations for approved and denied TAA petitioners, pooled across all periods (pre, during, and post-TAA).
Both samples are restricted to working-age individuals (22-65) making less than $50,000 annually in the pre-period, and restricted to first-time filers. The
“High Attachment” sample requires 2 years of positive earnings above the annual minimum wage equivalent prior to filing ($7.25 * 2,082 average working
hours in 2010 $15,000). Monetary variables are deflated to 2010 US dollars, seasonally adjusted, and winsorized at the 1% level to limit the influence of
outliers. Both samples contain 250 unique case investigators (rounded for confidentiality). See text for variable descriptions. Source: LEHD, USDOL
51
Table 3. Testing for Random Assignment of TAA Petitions to Investigators
Baseline TAA Approved Investigator Leniency F-Test [p-value]
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
A. Pre-Determined Demographics (LEHD)
Age (time of filing) 40.771 0.0007* (0.0004) -0.00007 (0.0001) -0.00002 (0.00004) -0.00002 (0.00004) [0.4437]
Female 0.5248 0.0281** (0.0118) 0.0015 (0.0019) -0.0005 (0.0009) -0.0006 (0.0009) [0.5166]
Black 0.1147 -0.0415* (0.0229) -0.0081** (0.0033) -0.0035 (0.0026) -0.0034 (0.0025) [0.3025]
White 0.7957 -0.0192 (0.0151) -0.0018 (0.0025) -0.0001 -0.0020 -0.0001 (0.0020) [0.2819]
High School Degree 0.3865 -0.0057 (0.0069) -0.0020 (0.0015) -0.0011 (0.0012) -0.0010 (0.0011) [0.8490]
Some College 0.2936 -0.0110 (0.0068) -0.00189 (0.0015) -0.0007 (0.0011) -0.0006 (0.0010) [0.3707]
College Degree 0.1173 -0.0224** (0.0089) -0.0014 (0.0021) -0.0013 (0.0011) -0.0012 (0.0011) [0.3110]
B. Pre-Determined Economic Variables (LEHD)
Annual Earnings ($1,000) 26.880 -0.0021*** (0.0006) -0.0002 (0.0001) -0.0001 (0.00007) -0.00007 (0.00007) [0.0917]
Quarters Employed 3.5566 -0.0060 (0.0048) 0.0011 (0.0012) 0.0007 (0.0008) 0.0006 (0.0008) [0.0627]
Quarters Employed (full-time equivalence) 3.2330 0.0154*** (0.0041) 0.0011 (0.0009) 0.0002 (0.0004) 0.0002 (0.0005) [0.0586]
Employed 0.9236 0.0420** (0.0189) -0.0040 (0.0027) -0.0025 (0.0025) -0.0021 (0.0025) [0.2100]
# of Jobs / Year 1.1120 -0.0007 (0.0008) 0.0002 (0.0002) 0.0002* (0.0001) 0.0002** (0.0001) [0.2325]
Tenure (years at separation) 5.0390 0.0012*** (0.0004) 0.0002** (0.0001) 0.0001** (0.0001) 0.0001** (0.0006) [0.0291]
Init. Employer Mean Earnings ($1,000) 23.159 0.0008 (0.0024) 0.0006 (0.0004) 0.0005 (0.0004) 0.0005 (0.0004) [0.1070]
County Unemployment Rate (time of filing) 6.6054 0.0070 (0.0059) -0.0001 (0.0012) 0.0005 (0.0009) 0.0008 (0.0009) [0.0952]
Prob(Employed at Petitioner Firm) 0.7409 -0.0114 (0.0171) 0.0005 (0.0022) -0.0012 (0.0019) -0.0012 (0.0019) [0.0423]
Prob(Employed at Petitioner 2-Digit NAICS) 0.7760 0.0177 (0.0211) -0.0004 (0.0029) -0.0007 (0.002) -0.0008 (0.0020) [0.7783]
Prob(Employed in Petitioner Commuting Zone) 0.6853 -0.0245 (0.0253) 0.0026 (0.0046) 0.0067** (0.0031) 0.0066** (0.0031) [0.4896]
C. Pre-Determined Petitioner Characteristics (DOL)
Company Filer 0.3267 0.2190*** (0.0436) 0.0024 (0.0072) 0.0012 (0.0079) 0.0016 (0.0079) [0.5251]
Union Filer 0.1415 -0.0068 (0.0491) -0.0043 (0.0086) -0.0038 (0.0085) -0.0038 (0.0086) [0.8211]
Worker-Group Filer 0.4354 -0.0643 (0.0469) 0.0001 (0.0070) -0.0024 (0.0075) -0.00152 (0.0074) [0.8612]
Investigator Caseload (no. of petitions) 23.2509 0.00001 (0.0009) -0.0003* (0.0002) -0.00008 (0.0002) -0.00005 (0.0002) [0.3175]
Investigator Tenure (decades) 0.9419 0.00002 (0.00003) -0.00004** (0.00002) -0.00004** (0.00002) -0.00004** (0.00002) [0.0177]
Prob(Tradable) (Mian & Sufi, 2011) 0.6008 0.0687** (0.0270) 0.0009 (0.0048) [0.0952]
Offshorability Z-Score (Blinder, 2007) 0.3076 0.0032 (0.0176) -0.0058** (0.0025) [0.0967]
Offshorability Z-Score (Autor & Dorn, 2013) 0.2533 -0.0121 (0.0103) -0.0021 (0.0018) [0.1812]
Filer Industry FEs (4-digit SIC) yes yes yes
Investigator Concentration Controls yes yes
Joint F-Test [p-value] [0.0000] [0.0409] [0.2033] [0.1801] [0.1801]
Number of Petitioners 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300
Number of Employers 86,000 86,000 86,000 86,000 86,000
Number of Displaced Workers 177,000 177,000 177,000 177,000 177,000
Number of Observations 1,381,000 1,381,000 1,381,000 1,381,000 1,381,000
NOTES—This table tests for random assignment of TAA petitions to DOL investigators. Observations are pooled from eligible separating workers in the
“High Attachment” sample 40 to 5 quarters before their petition decision, and restricted to first-time filers. The sample includes working-age individuals
(22-65) making under $50,000 annually in the pre-period, with 2 years above the annual minimum wage equivalent prior to filing ($7.25 * 2,082 average
working hours in 2010 $15,000). Column (1) reports the baseline mean. The dependent variable in column (2) is an indicator for TAA approval.
The dependent variable in columns (3) to (5) is the investigator leniency IV. Column (6) shows p-values from separate regressions of the leniency IV on
each covariate. Monetary variables are deflated to 2010 US dollars, seasonally adjusted, and winsorized at 1% to limit outlier influence. All regressions
contain quarter-of-filing and calendar-year fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at the investigator level. ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.10. Source:
LEHD,USDOL
52
Table 4. TAA Approval and Investigator Leniency (First Stage)
1(TAA) 1(TAA) 1(TAA) 1(TAA) 1(TAA)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Leniency (Leave-One-Out) 0.646*** 0.613*** 0.639*** 0.615*** 0.592***
(0.11) (0.11) (0.12) (0.12) (0.11)
Investigator # of Cases in Industry (N
jkt
) 0.00274*** 0.00278*** 0.00270*** 0.00268*** 0.00296***
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Investigator Concentration in Industry (C
jkt
) -0.524*** -0.499*** -0.508*** -0.481*** -0.411***
(0.11) (0.11) (0.12) (0.12) (0.11)
Investigator Caseload (No. of Petitions) -0.0001 -0.0002 -0.0003
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Investigator Tenure (Decades) 0.000003 0.000003 0.000004*
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Filer Industry FEs (4-Digit SIC) yes yes yes yes yes
Calendar-Year & Filer-Quarter FEs yes yes yes yes
Baseline Controls yes yes
Full Regression Controls yes
Number of Petitioners 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300
Number of Displaced Workers 177,000 177,000 177,000 177,000 177,000
Number of Observations 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000
F-Statistic on Excluded IV 32.76 29.07 31.04 27.63 27.21
NOTES—This table reports first stage estimates corresponding to equation (1) of the paper for the “High
Attachment” sample, which includes working-age individuals (22-65) making under $50,000 annually in the
pre-period, with 2 years above the annual minimum wage equivalent prior to filing ($7.25 * 2,082 average
working hours in 2010 $15,000). Baseline Controls include means over 5 to 40 quarters prior to the TAA petition
decision for the following variables: worker earnings, quarters employed, worker tenure, and initial employer
and state earnings. Full Regression Controls reflect covariates estimated in the paper’s preferred specification, and
include: race and gender fixed effects, a cubic in age fully interacted with baseline earnings and gender indicators,
filer-state fixed effects, filer-type fixed effects (company, union, worker-group), and a dummy variable for whether
a petition applied as part of the NAFTA-TAA program (see text). Monetary variables are deflated to 2010 US
dollars, seasonally adjusted, and winsorized at the 1% level to limit the influence of outliers. Standard errors (in
parentheses) are clustered at the investigator level. ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.10. Source: LEHD, USDOL.
53
Table 5. Pooled Effects of TAA on Annual Earnings ($)
OLS 2SLS
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
A. Post-Training
1(TAA Approved) -963.8*** 14,474.4* 14,335.4* 14,812.3* 13,112.8** 10,255.9**
(250.2) (8211.1) (8449.8) (8383) (6432.3) (5086.7)
B. Pre-Training [Placebo]
1(TAA Approved) -150.9 405.4 313.1 169.2 266.9 333.8
(246.7) (480.1) (499.8) (514.2) (677.8) (660.1)
Identification Controls:
Filer Industry FEs (4-digit SIC) yes yes yes yes yes yes
Investigator Concentration Controls yes yes yes yes yes yes
Precision Controls:
Calendar Year & Filer Quarter FEs yes yes yes yes yes yes
Baseline Controls yes yes yes yes
Filer Type & NAFTA-TAA FEs yes yes yes
Filer State FEs yes yes
Demographic Controls yes
Number of Petitioners 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300
Number of Workers 177,000 177,000 177,000 177,000 177,0000 177,000
Number of Observations (All Periods) 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000
NOTES—This table reports the main effects of TAA on annual earnings, pooled in the “post” and “pre” periods
separately such that each column presents two regression coefficients. Each specification corresponds to equation
(2) of the paper for the “High Attachment” sample, which includes working-age individuals (22-65) making under
$50,000 annually in the pre-period, with 2 years above the annual minimum wage equivalent prior to filing ($7.25
* 2,082 average working hours in 2010 $15,000). Baseline Controls include means over 5 to 40 quarters prior to
the TAA petition decision for the following variables: worker earnings, quarters employed, worker tenure, and
initial employer and state earnings. Demographic Controls include: race and gender fixed effects, a cubic in age
fully interacted with baseline earnings and gender indicators. Filer-type fixed effects indicate whether a petition
was filed by a company, union, worker-group, or career center (omitted). NAFTA-TAA is a dummy variable for
whether a petition applied as part of the NAFTA-TAA program (see text). Monetary variables are deflated to 2010
US dollars, seasonally adjusted, and winsorized at the 1% level to limit the influence of outliers. Standard errors
(in parentheses) are clustered at the investigator level. ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.10. Source: LEHD, USDOL
54
Table 6. Pooled Effects of TAA on Quarters Employed
OLS 2SLS
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
A. Post-Training
1(TAA Approved) -0.0127 1.368* 1.209* 1.175* 0.795** 0.642**
(0.72) (0.72) (0.62) (0.61) (0.38) (0.32)
B. Pre-Training [Placebo]
1(TAA Approved) -0.00116 0.43 0.0193 0.0157 0.0466 0.0587
(0.01) (0.30) (0.05) (0.05) (0.08) (0.08)
Identification Controls:
Filer Industry FEs (4-digit SIC) yes yes yes yes yes yes
Investigator Concentration Controls yes yes yes yes yes yes
Precision Controls:
Calendar Year & Filer Quarter FEs yes yes yes yes yes yes
Baseline Controls yes yes yes yes
Filer Type & NAFTA-TAA FEs yes yes yes
Filer State FEs yes yes
Demographic Controls yes
Number of Petitioners 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300
Number of Workers 177,000 177,000 177,000 177,000 177,0000 177,000
Number of Observations (All Periods) 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000
NOTES—This table reports the main effects of TAA on quarters employed, pooled in the “post” and “pre” periods
separately such that each column presents two regression coefficients. Each specification corresponds to equation
(2) of the paper for the “High Attachment” sample, which includes working-age individuals (22-65) making under
$50,000 annually in the pre-period, with 2 years above the annual minimum wage equivalent prior to filing ($7.25
* 2,082 average working hours in 2010 $15,000). Baseline Controls include means over 5 to 40 quarters prior to
the TAA petition decision for the following variables: worker earnings, quarters employed, worker tenure, and
initial employer and state earnings. Demographic Controls include: race and gender fixed effects, a cubic in age
fully interacted with baseline earnings and gender indicators. Filer-type fixed effects indicate whether a petition
was filed by a company, union, worker-group, or career center (omitted). NAFTA-TAA is a dummy variable for
whether a petition applied as part of the NAFTA-TAA program (see text). Monetary variables are deflated to 2010
US dollars, seasonally adjusted, and winsorized at the 1% level to limit the influence of outliers. Standard errors
(in parentheses) are clustered at the investigator level. ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.10. Source: LEHD, USDOL
55
Table 7. Pooled Effects of TAA on Formal Education
OLS 2SLS
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
A. Post-Training
1(TAA Approved) -0.0183 -0.233 -0.133 -0.081 -0.15
(0.01) (0.22) (0.2) (0.18) (0.16)
B. Pre-Training [Placebo]
1(TAA Approved) -0.0106 -0.0605 -0.0159 -0.00948 -0.188
(0.01) (0.19) (0.18) (0.17) (0.18)
Identification Controls:
Filer Industry FEs (4-digit SIC) yes yes yes yes yes
Investigator Concentration Controls yes yes yes yes yes
Precision Controls:
Calendar Year & Filer Quarter FEs yes yes yes yes yes
Baseline Controls yes yes yes
Filer Type & NAFTA-TAA FEs yes yes
Demographic Controls & State FEs yes
Number of Petitioners 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300 4,300
Number of Workers 177,000 177,000 177,000 177,000 177,000
Number of Observations (All Periods) 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000 2,623,000
Baseline Education Value 2 2 2 2 2
NOTES—This table reports the main effects of TAA on formal education, pooled in the “post” and “pre” periods
separately such that each column presents two regression coefficients. Ordinal education values reflect combined
imputed and non-imputed decennial census estimates which are merged to the Census LEHD based on a
scrambled social security identifier. 1=Some High School; 2=High School Degree; 3=Some College; 4=College
Degree. Each specification corresponds to equation (2) of the paper for the “High Attachment” sample, which
includes working-age individuals (22-65) making under $50,000 annually in the pre-period, with 2 years above
the annual minimum wage equivalent prior to filing ($7.25 * 2,082 average working hours in 2010 $15,000).
Baseline Controls include means over 5 to 40 quarters prior to the TAA petition decision for the following variables:
worker earnings, quarters employed, worker tenure, and initial employer and state earnings. Demographic Controls
include: race and gender fixed effects, a cubic in age fully interacted with baseline earnings and gender indicators.
Filer-type fixed effects indicate whether a petition was filed by a company, union, worker-group, or career center
(omitted). NAFTA-TAA is a dummy variable for whether a petition applied as part of the NAFTA-TAA program
(see text). Monetary variables are deflated to 2010 US dollars, seasonally adjusted, and winsorized at the 1% level
to limit the influence of outliers. Standard errors (in parentheses) are clustered at the investigator level. ***p<0.01,
**p<0.05, *p<0.10. Source: LEHD, USDOL
56
Table 8. Event Year Coefficient Estimates by Heterogeneity Groupings
Earnings ($) Pr(Stays in Initial CZ) Pr(Stays in Initial NAICS)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Event Year (τ ) High Training Low Training High Low High Low
Duration Duration Shock Shock Shock Shock
0 -9,357.12** -5,432.05 -0.3231 -0.1044 0.0052 -0.2405*
1 -4,015.65 459.38 -0.3810* -0.4943** -0.2287 -0.5293*
2 4,324.40 10,001.72 -0.3083* -0.3178 -0.3461* -0.4958
3 7,629.67 12,370.85 -0.3819* 0.0704 -0.5085** 0.1071
4 6,972.06 11,692.10* -0.3288** 0.2292 -0.5104*** 0.3335
5 6,766.97* 7,730.66* -0.3211* 0.1521 -0.4310** 0.2651
6 9,626.92** 6,971.34* -0.2970* 0.2007 -0.3746** 0.6994*
7 9,608.34** 6,317.66 -0.3172* 0.2482 -0.3941** 0.6446
8 5,931.00* 4,201.82 -0.2486* 0.2721 -0.2688* 0.5458
9 5,776.88* 4,278.90 -0.2023* -0.0301 -0.2833* 0.4003
Identification Controls:
Filer Industry FEs (4-digit SIC) yes yes yes yes yes yes
Investigator Concentration Controls yes yes yes yes yes yes
Precision Controls:
Calendar Year & Filer Quarter FEs yes yes yes yes yes yes
Baseline Controls yes yes yes yes yes yes
Filer Type & NAFTA-TAA FEs yes yes yes yes yes yes
Demographic Controls & State FEs yes yes yes yes yes yes
No. of Workers 177,000 177,000 177,000
NOTES—This table shows 2SLS coefficient estimates of the effect of TAA on the dependent variable and
sub-group indicated for the main analysis sample—“High Labor Force Attachment”. Columns (1) and
(2) correspond to Figure 10. Columns (3) through (6) correspond to Figure 12. Number of displaced
workers are rounded as per Census Bureau confidentiality requirements. Each point estimate is from
a separate cross-sectional regression for the event year relative to the TAA petition decision (τ = 0).
Standard errors clustered at the investigator level. ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.10. Source: LEHD; USDOL
57
Appendices
Appendix A. Data Appendix
A.1 LEHD Sample Construction and TAA Matching
This appendix provides additional detail on how the LEHD sample of workers is constructed. The main
sample consists of worker histories for separating workers associated with both approved and denied
TAA petitions, flagged as “separated” if observed moving from positive to zero earnings in the TAA
eligibility window.
67
Workers in each state are observed if they were employed between the following
quarter and 2011q4:
1985q2: MD
1990q1: CO, IL, IN, KS, WA, MO
1991q1: OR, PA
1991q3: CA
1992q1: AZ
1992q4: FL
1993q1: MT
1995q3: NM
1996q1: ME
1997q1: WV
1998q1: NV, SC, TN
1998q3: DE
1998q4: IA
2000q1: OK
2002q2: DC
2002q3: AR
To identify TAA filers at the worker-level, I first have to identify both the correct TAA petitioner plant,
and the timing of the separation event in the LEHD. I restrict attention to all petitions filed between 1990
and 2011. Matching is done in several steps:
Step 1. Match TAA petitioner list (USDOL list of first-time TAA claims against establishments)
separately on cleaned address and company name strings within each state, to the Standard Statistical
Establishment List (SSEL) single- and multi-unit files for the calendar year and year prior to the
petition(to account for potential filing lags or measurement error in filing dates).
Step 2. Keep SSEL establishments if the matched address or company name is unique to an EIN in
a given state-year cell. By focusing on one-to-one matches, this circumvents problems arising from
matching one TAA establishment address to a Census location containing many establishments at the
same address (such as an office building). This is especially important when there is a small expected
effect size but large variation in the outcome variable, or compliance is imperfect, as is known to be the
case with TAA (Schochet et al., 2012). The sample thus reflects a very conservative match, but also one
with external validity representative of rural, stand-alone, manufacturing plants.
Step 3. Draw three random samples of 100 matches (without replacement) and manually verify rate at
which SSEL establishment names match TAA establishment names.
68
Step 4. Using the LEHD Employer Characteristics File (ECF), assign all units at each SEIN (State
Employer Identification Number) a matched SSEL establishment (if a match exists) by merging the two
datasets on federal EIN (Employer Identification Number using the LEHD-provided es ein variable).
69
67
This definition of separation allows for a greater sample size, however all results are robust to using “mass layoff
definitions in which greater than 30% of employees are laid off, “displacement” definitions in which workers make less than
70% of their prior earnings in the post-period, and restrictions that only keep workers who are unemployed for more than 2
quarters (eliminating potential measurement error).
68
Match rates for all three samples are greater than 98%, with the residual owing to likely discrepancies between parent and
subsidiary names which could not be reconciled between the two datasets.
69
One limitation to this strategy is that some units will be included as part of an EIN but not part the petitioning plant.
58
Then, using the SEIN, pull the full worker history for any worker that separated in the TAA eligibility
window (shown in Section 2.2) from the Employee History File (EHF). Workers can furnish returns
from multiple employers, but earnings are aggregated (collapsed) such that each worker only has
one earnings observation per quarter. In cases where workers have multiple jobs, I ascribe them the
majority-earning SEIN when estimating mobility effects.
Importantly, a worker is marked unemployed if she is observed subsequently reemployed after having a
missing earnings observation. However, I cannot distinguish between the following cases if the worker
is not observed as reemployed (censored):
Worker is discouraged / out of labor force
Worker moved to state outside approved sample (otherwise workers can be tracked across states)
Worker is on long-term disability / has retired / is deceased
Worker is self-employed
A.2 Tradability and Offshorability Indices
In some sense, the mean approval rate across different TAA industries forms an implicit index of
industry tradability or offshorability as perceived by TAA case investigators. To show how well
investigator approval rates map to known indices in the literature, I use three industry-level measures.
I first take the offshorability score assigned by Blinder (2007) to each occupation code (O*Net OCC
10.0, last revised in 1991), which also contains Department of Labor 6-digit Standard Occupational
Classification (SOC) codes. Using the BLS Occupational Employment Statistics (OES) national industry
estimates that show the most common SOC occupations for each 6-digit NAICS industry, I compute a
weighted sum of the offshorability index within each industry, multiplying the share of employees in
a given occupation times the offshorability score. I then divide this by its standard deviation to have a
comparable standardized measure across industries.
I repeat this exact same procedure for 1990 occupational codes provided by Autor and Dorn (2013), who
base their offshorability measures on face-to-face and on-site interaction requirements used in Firpo et
al. (2011). Finally, Mian and Sufi (2014) provide their own measure of tradability based on geographic
concentration. Normalizing all three measures, I can compare them and how well they correlate with
mean TAA approval rates across 3-digit NAICS codes.
A.3 Marginal Value of Public Funds Approach to Welfare
Hendren (2016) provides a framework in which welfare effects of policies are sufficiently characterized
by individuals’ induced behavioral response and fiscal externalities on government outlays (which in
this case includes 35 cents lost in moral hazard costs for every dollar of spending on UI ( = .345), as
well as additional tax revenue levied on TAA returns (τ, assumed to be equal to 0.3), without making
explicit assumptions about excess burden or deadweight loss.
MVPF =
Private WTP for TAA
Fiscal Externality
=
$43, 398
$40, 362(1 + τ )
= 1.14 (10)
The numerator here is the discounted 10 year earnings flow net of private costs (r=.05), while the
denominator includes behavioral and direct effects on government outlays. Here, two years of TAA
Unfortunately the LEHD does not contain reliable addresses at the unit-level, however in robustness checks, I find that results
are qualitatively similar when confining the sample to single-unit EINs.
59
directly costs the government $40,362 per individual assuming each individual exhausts maximal
benefits. Relaxing this assumption (for example of the average recipient only takes TAA for 1.5 years)
would decrease government costs while keeping returns constant, and thus increase the MVPF.
As discussed in the main text, this measure represents an understatement of true benefits for two
further reasons. First, to the extent that TAA induces participants away from entitlement payments
such as welfare and disability insurance, fiscal externalities are understated (e.g. estimates from a
randomized trail analyzing the 1982 Job Training Partnership ACT suggest that these savings could
amount to 34 cents on the dollar, in which case one would subtract 0.34 from the term in parentheses on
the denominator, which would greatly increase up the MVPF (Hendren, 2016)). Secondly, benefits here
reflect intent-to-treat estimates, and need to be scaled up to reflect imperfect compliance. For this reason,
an MVPF value suggesting each dollar of TAA has a social return of 1.14 dollars should be viewed as a
lower bound.
70
70
One important caveat here however, is that the MVPF framework invokes the envelope theorem which implicitly assumes
that any worker induced into TAA was on the margin indifferent between working and not working. For the willingness to pay
to be above program cost suggest some departure from the assumption that workers are at a local optimum, such as additional
human capital externalities, present bias, or adjustment frictions, consistent with the results shown here.
60
Appendix B. Additional Figures
Figure B.1 Raw Earnings Differences by 2-Digit Industry
NOTES—This figure expresses mean earnings differences between certified and denied TAA applicants by 2-digit
SIC codes (thin gray lines), overlaid with the aggregate difference from the top panel of Figure 4 (bold series) for
the main analysis sample: working-age individuals (22-65) with 2 years of positive earnings above the annual
minimum wage equivalent prior to filing ($7.25 * 2,082 average working hours in 2010 $15,000), earning less
than $50,000 annually in the pre-period. Monetary variables are deflated to 2010 US dollars, seasonally adjusted,
and winsorized at 1% to limit outliers. Source: LEHD; USDOL
61
Figure B.2 Local Average Treatment Effect (LATE) Compliers
NOTES—This figure highlights the types of workers and firms that are likely to comply with the TAA investigator
leniency instrument—i.e. LATE compliers—those indicated by the middle bracket in each panel. The left panel
orders mean industry approval rates from lowest to highest by 3-digit NAICS codes, calculated over all TAA
cases from 1974 to 2016. Overlaid is a standard measure of tradability calculated from Blinder (2007) for the
same industries. (See Appendix A.2 for details on the construction of this index at the industry level, as well
as other tradablility measures from Mian and Sufi (2014) and Autor and Dorn (2013).) The right panel shows
within-industry investigator variation around the same mean approval rates, where the median is indicated
with a black dot and whiskers reflect the 35th to 65th leniency percentiles within each industry. Each 1(TAA)
approval decision can be thought of as a latent variable sum of an observable tradability signal (left) and subjective
adjudication noise (right). 85% of workers are associated with leniency rates between 20% and 80% (i.e. marginal
cases), rather than with industries that are generally always denied or approved benefits. Source: USDOL (OTAA)
petition database attained via FOIA request
62
Figure B.3 Dynamic Effects of TAA on Annual Earnings, Full Sample
NOTES—This plots shows 2SLS coefficient estimates of the effects of TAA on annual earnings for the unrestricted
“High and Low Labor Force Attachment” sample (287,000 displaced workers), as robustness to the preferred
sample estimates in Figure 7. Coefficients are estimated for each event year relative to the TAA petition decision
(τ = 0), such that each point estimate is from a separate cross-sectional regression. Vertical lines partition the
support into pre-TAA, during-TAA, and post-TAA periods. Sample restrictions and variable definitions are
identical to those described in Table 5, column 6 (the paper’s preferred earnings specification), except workers
are not required to have 2 years above the annual minimum wage equivalent prior to filing. Dotted lines represent
90% confidence intervals with standard errors clustered at the investigator level. Source: LEHD; USDOL
63
Figure B.4 Dynamic Effects of TAA on Log Earnings
NOTES—This plot shows 2SLS coefficient estimates for the effects of TAA on log earnings as an alternative
specification to (Figure 8 (effects on quarters employed). Estimates are shown dynamically across event years
relative to the TAA petition decision (τ = 0). Each point estimate is from a separate cross-sectional regression
by event year. Vertical lines partition the support into pre-TAA, during-TAA, and post-TAA periods. Sample
restrictions and variable definitions are identical to those described in Table 5, column 6, except non-zero earnings
quarters are eliminated by logging. Dotted lines represent 90% confidence intervals with standard errors clustered
at the investigator level. Source: LEHD; USDOL
64
Figure B.5 Composition of TAA Spending Across States & Time
NOTES—This figure displays median TAA expenditures on training and extended UI (Trade Readjustment
Allowances (TRA)), along with their inter-quartile range across states within each year. Data reflects spending
on recipients known to have participated for at least one day in training or TRA. The large variation in
extended UI rates depend partly on different initial UI generosities and formulae across states (see Department
of Labor Unemployment Insurance Data Summary), and partly on legislative changes and automatic stabilizers
implemented during the Great Recession. Source: USDOL Trade Act Participant Report (TAPR), 2001 to 2016
65
Figure B.6 Effects of TAA on Earnings for CZ and Industry “Stayers”
NOTES—This figure shows 2SLS estimates of the effects of TAA for workers who stay in their initial commuting
zones (top) and 2-digit NAICS industries (bottom) in the post-period. This ex-post definition of mobility is used as a
subgroup in a specification similar to equation (5) of the draft, where only coefficients on stayers are plotted here.
Stayers comprise approximately 53% and 44% of the sample for commuting zones and industries respectively.
Each point estimate is from a separate regression by event year. Vertical lines partition the pre-TAA, during-TAA,
and post-TAA periods. Sample restrictions and variable definitions are identical to those described in Table 5,
column 6. Dotted lines represent 90% confidence intervals with standard errors clustered at the investigator level.
Source: LEHD; USDOL
66
Figure B.7 Workers Filing for TAA: All (Top) versus LEHD Sample (Bottom),
Weighted by 2010 Zip Code Population (1,000 people)
NOTES—These maps show the cumulative number of TAA filers by 1990 commuting zone (geographies taken
from Dorn (2009)). The top sample reflects the universe of TAA filers from 1974 to 2016. The bottom sample
displays all filers in 24 LEHD-approved states from 1990 to 2011, forming the basis of the matched analysis sample.
Both maps display cumulative numbers by quintile. Source: USDOL (OTAA) petition database attained via FOIA
request; US Census Bureau 2000 decennial census
67
Figure B.8 Effects of TAA on Worker Mobility by Initial Labor Market Strength
NOTES—This figure shows two series of 2SLS estimates, corresponding to each β
1τ
and β
2τ
of equation (5) of
the draft where the dependent variables are the probability that a worker is employed in the same commuting
zone (top) and 2-digit NAICS industry (bottom) as the region and industry from which they initially separated.
Estimates are broken out by high and low shock unemployment regions, where each point estimate is from a
separate regression by event year. Commuting zones are defined by 1990 boundaries originally geocoded by
Dorn (2009). Baseline mobility rates can be found in Table 3, column 1. Vertical lines partition the pre-TAA,
during-TAA, and post-TAA periods. Sample restrictions and variable definitions are identical to those described
in Table 6, column 6. Standard errors are suppressed for exposition. See online appendix for underlying data,
and Figure 13 for corresponding earnings responses by mobility groups. Source: LEHD; USDOL; BLS Local Area
Unemployment Statistics (LAUS)
68
Appendix C. Additional Tables
Table C.1 Dynamic Earnings Coefficient Estimates by Event Year
High Attachment High & Low Attachment
Event Year (τ ) β
τ
Std. Error β
τ
Std. Error
0 -8,117.04* (4376.39) -5,632.83* (3,333.45)
1 -2,658.47 (4297.99) -1,160.72 (3590.28)
2 6,350.23 (4789.55) 4,748.69 (3832.99)
3 9,259.34 (5885.42) 7,810.82* (4464.60)
4 8714.95* (4781.49) 8,374.10** (3834.50)
5 7186.63* (3692.48) 7,212.00** (3,318.52)
6 8374.69** (3790.21) 7,413.26** (3,378.17)
7 7948.48** (3871.13) 7,757.00** (3,552.50)
8 4845.18* (2808.49) 4,235.00* (2,221.53)
9 5012.91* (2734.88) 5,511.12*** (2,093.29)
10 978.67 (1421.35) 1,294.62 (1,041.89)
Identification Controls:
Filer Industry FEs (4-digit SIC) yes yes
Investigator Concentration Controls yes yes
Precision Controls:
Calendar Year & Filer Quarter FEs yes yes
Baseline Controls yes yes
Filer Type & NAFTA-TAA FEs yes yes
Demographic Controls & State FEs yes yes
No. of Workers 177,000 287,000
No. of Observations (Total) 2,623,000 4,192,000
NOTES—This table shows 2SLS coefficient estimates of the effect of TAA on annual earnings by event
year. “High Attachment” estimates correspond to the main analysis sample of workers that are highly
attached to the labor force (see Figure 7 for corresponding graph and sample restrictions). “High and
Low Attachment” estimates correspond to the unrestricted sample (see Figure 7 for corresponding
graph and sample restrictions). Number of displaced workers are rounded as per Census Bureau
confidentiality requirements. Each point estimate is from a separate cross-sectional regression for the
event year relative to the TAA petition decision (τ = 0). Standard errors clustered at the investigator
level. ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.10. Source: LEHD; USDOL
69
Table C.2. Reduced Form Equation, Robustness to Control Choice
Annual Annual Annual Annual Annual Annual Annual Annual Annual
Earnings ($) Earnings ($) Earnings ($) Earnings ($) Earnings ($) Earnings ($) Earnings ($) Earnings ($) Earnings ($)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (8)
Leniency (Leave-One-Out) 5012*** 2709* 2895* 3449** 5621*** 7251*** 5989*** 5689*** 4800***
(1716) (1514) (1575) (1539) (1516) (1537) (1912) (1930) (1504)
Calendar Year & Filer-Quarter FEs yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes
Offshorability Z-Score (Autor & Dorn, 2013) yes
Offshorability Z-Score (Blinder, 2007) yes
Prob(Tradable) (Mian and Sufi, 2011) yes
2-Digit SIC Filer FEs yes
3-Digit SIC Filer FEs yes
4-Digit SIC Filer FEs yes yes yes
Investigator Concentration Controls yes yes
Full Regression Controls yes
2SLS Pre-Trend Slope -1291 -1291 -1291 -1291 -1344 -1407 -1193 -1014 357.1
Joint F (P-value), τ [1, 3] 0.000111*** 0.000111*** 0.000111*** 0.000111*** 0.0001397*** 0.00007298*** 0.1233 0.1014 0.1014
Joint F (P-value), τ [4, 6] 0.1387 0.1387 0.1387 0.1387 0.1376 0.3103 0.1642 0.137 0.137
Joint F (P-value), τ [7, 10] 0.2042 0.2042 0.2042 0.2042 0.5757 0.2193 0.5479 0.6951 0.6951
Number of Workers (Post) 155,000 155,000 155,000 155,000 155,000 155,000 155,000 155,000 155,000
Number of Observations (Post) 901,000 901,000 901,000 901,000 901,000 901,000 901,000 901,000 901,000
NOTES—This table shows how the reduced form equation varies with the choice of quasi-experimental controls included in the regression. The top portion
of the table shows how adding different quasi-experimental controls affects both the overall point estimate, and the 2SLS pretrend from a linear fit over
event-year specific point estimates in the pre-period. The bottom portion uses a more granular version of the necessary condition of pretrend balance
in covariates, showing the p-value from a joint F-tests across different 3-year sections of the support including all baseline covariates from the original
balance test (not indicated above), in addition to the fixed effects listed above. Standard errors clustered at the investigator level. See text for further details.
***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.10. Source: LEHD, USDOL
70