Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 1 of 27
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
_________________________________________
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,
Plaintiff,
v.
CHARTER COMMUNICATIONS, INC.,
TIME WARNER CABLE INC,
ADVANCE/NEWHOUSE PARTNERSHIP, and
BRIGHT HOUSE NETWORKS, LLC,
Defendants.
Civil Action No. 1:16-cv-00759 (RCL)
COMPETITIVE IMPACT STATEMENT
The United States of America (“United States”), pursuant to Section 2(b) of the Antitrust
Procedures and Penalties Act (“APPA” or “Tunney Act”), 15 U.S.C. § 16(b)-(h), files this
Competitive Impact Statement relating to the proposed Final Judgment submitted for entry in
this civil antitrust proceeding.
I. NATURE AND PURPOSE OF THE PROCEEDING
On May 23, 2015, Charter Communications, Inc. (“Charter”) and Time Warner Cable,
Inc. (“TWC”), two of the largest cable companies in the United States, agreed to merge in a deal
valued at over $78 billion. In addition, Charter and Advance/ Newhouse Partnership, which
owns Bright House Networks, LLC (“BHN”), announced that Charter would acquire BHN for
$10.4 billion, conditional on the sale of TWC to Charter. As a result of these transactions, the
combined company, referred to as “New Charter,” will become one of the largest providers of
pay television service in the United States.
The United States filed a civil antitrust Complaint on April 25, 2016, seeking to enjoin
the proposed transactions because their likely effect would be to lessen competition substantially
2
in numerous local markets for the timely distribution of professional, full-length video
programming to residential customers (“video programming distribution”) throughout the United
States in violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 18. Specifically, the Complaint
alleges that the proposed merger would increase the ability and incentive of New Charter to use
its leverage with video programmers to limit the access of online video distributors (“OVDs”) to
important content. These OVDs are increasingly offering meaningful competition to cable
companies like Charter, and the loss of competition caused by the proposed merger likely would
result in lower-quality services, fewer choices, and higher prices for consumers, as well as
reduced investment and less innovation in this dynamic industry.
At the same time the Complaint was filed, the United States also filed a Stipulation and
proposed Final Judgment, which are designed to eliminate the anticompetitive effects of the
proposed merger. Under the proposed Final Judgment, which is explained more fully below, the
Defendants will be prohibited from using their bargaining leverage with video programmers to
inhibit the flow of video content to OVDs. The proposed Final Judgment will provide a prompt,
certain, and effective remedy for consumers by preventing New Charter from using its leverage
over programmers to harm competition. The United States and the Defendants have stipulated
that the proposed Final Judgment may be entered after compliance with the APPA. Entry of the
proposed Final Judgment would terminate this action, except that the Court would retain
jurisdiction to construe, modify, or enforce the provisions of the proposed Final Judgment, and to
punish and remedy violations thereof.
The proposed merger was also subject to review and approval by the Federal
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 2 of 27
3
Communications Commission (“FCC”).
1
On May 5, 2016, the FCC adopted an order approving
the transactions subject to certain conditions discussed below, and that order was released
publicly on May 10, 2016. The Department and the FCC coordinated closely in their reviews of
the proposed merger. The FCC’s remedy is independent of the proposed Final Judgment and not
subject to review in this proceeding.
II. DESCRIPTION OF THE EVENTS GIVING
RISE TO THE ALLEGED VIOLATION
A. The Defendants and the Proposed Merger
Charter is the third-largest cable company in the United States, and the sixth-largest
multichannel video programming distributor (“MVPD”) overall. Charter owns cable systems
across 28 states, serving approximately 4.8 million residential broadband customers and 4.2
million residential video customers. Charter reported total revenues of around $9.1 billion in
2014, approximately $4.4 billion of which were derived from Charter’s video business.
TWC is the second-largest cable company in the United States (behind only Comcast
Corp.), and the fourth-largest MVPD in the country. TWC’s cable systems serve approximately
11.7 million residential broadband and 10.8 million residential video customers in 30 states.
TWC reported total revenues of approximately $22.8 billion in 2014, around $10.4 billion of
which were derived from TWC’s video business.
BHN is the sixth-largest incumbent cable company in the United States and the ninth-
largest MVPD overall. It owns cable systems serving approximately 2 million video customers
across six states, the majority of whom are located in the Orlando and Tampa-St. Petersburg,
Florida areas. BHN is a wholly-owned subsidiary of Advance/Newhouse Partnership. Although
1
Under the Communications Act, the FCC has jurisdiction to determine whether mergers
involving the transfer of a telecommunications license are in the “public interest, convenience,
and necessity.” 47 U.S.C. § 310(d).
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 3 of 27
4
the Advance/Newhouse Partnership retains the authority to manage BHN, it has entered into
agreements by which TWC performs certain functions for BHN, including the procurement of
cable programming. In 2014, BHN generated total revenues of around $3.7 billion,
approximately $1.5 billion of which were derived from its video business.
The proposed transactions combining Charter, TWC, and BHN into New Charter, as
initially agreed to by the Defendants on May 23, 2015, would lessen competition substantially in
numerous local markets for video programming distribution. These transactions are the subject
of the Complaint and proposed Final Judgment filed by the United States on April 25, 2016.
B. The Structure of the Video Programming Distribution Industry
The video programming distribution industry operates at two distinct levels. At the
“upstream” level, video programmers license their content to video programming distributors –
both OVDs and traditional MVPDs including Charter, TWC, and BHN. At the “downstream”
level, the video programming distributors then sell subscriptions to various packages of that
content and deliver the content to residential customers.
1. Video Programmers
Video programmers produce themselves, or acquire from other copyright holders, a
collection of professional, full-length programs and movies. These video programmers then
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 4 of 27
5
typically aggregate this content into branded networks (e.g., NBC or The History Channel) that
provide a 24-hour schedule that is attractive to consumers. Large video programmers often own
multiple individual networks. For instance, The Walt Disney Company owns the ABC broadcast
network as well as many cable networks such as ESPN and The Disney Channel.
In order to acquire the rights to distribute each network, video programming distributors
pay the video programmer a license fee, generally on a per-subscriber basis. These license fees
are an important revenue stream for video programmers. Most of the remainder of their revenues
comes from fees for advertisements placed on their networks.
Video programmers rely on video programming distributors – both MVPDs and OVDs
to reach consumers. Unless a video programmer obtains carriage in the packages of video
programming distributors that reach a sufficient number of consumers, the programmers will be
unable to earn enough revenue in licensing or to attract enough advertising revenue to generate a
return on their investments in content. For this reason, video programmers prefer to have as
many video programming distributors as possible carry their networks, and particularly seek out
the largest MVPDs that reach the most customers. If the programmer is unable to agree on
acceptable terms with a particular distributor, the programmer’s content will not be available to
that distributor’s customers. This potential consequence gives the largest MVPDs significant
bargaining leverage in their negotiations with programmers.
2. Multichannel Video Programming Distributors
Traditional video programming distributors include incumbent cable companies such as
Charter and TWC; direct broadcast satellite (“DBS”) providers such as DirecTV and DISH
Network; telephone companies (“telcos”) that offer video services such as Verizon and AT&T;
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 5 of 27
6
and overbuilders such as Google Fiber and RCN.
2
These distributors are referred to collectively
as MVPDs. MVPDs typically offer hundreds of channels of professional video programming to
residential customers for a monthly subscription fee.
3. Online Video Programming Distributors
OVDs are relatively recent entrants into the video programming distribution market.
They deliver a variety of live and/or on-demand video programming over the Internet, whether
streamed to Internet-connected televisions or other devices, or downloaded for later viewing.
OVDs today include services like Netflix, Hulu, Amazon Prime Instant Video, and Sling TV,
although, as discussed in more detail below, their content selection and business models vary
greatly. Unlike MVPDs, OVDs do not own distribution facilities and are dependent upon
broadband Internet access service providers, including incumbent cable companies such as
Charter and TWC, for the delivery of their content to viewers.
C. The Relevant Market and Market Concentration
The Complaint alleges that video programming distribution constitutes a relevant product
market and line of commerce under Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 18. The market
for video programming distribution includes both traditional MVPDs and their newer OVD
rivals.
Consumers purchase video programming distribution services from among those
distributors that can offer such services directly to their home. The DBS operators, DirecTV and
DISH, can reach almost any customer in the continental United States who has an unobstructed
line of sight to their satellites. OVDs are available to any consumer with an Internet service
sufficient to deliver video of an acceptable quality. In contrast, wireline-based distributors such
2
Overbuilders are providers who have constructed an additional wired network to residential
consumers for offering video and broadband service (i.e., they have “built over” the cable and
phone company networks).
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 6 of 27
7
as cable companies and telcos generally must obtain a franchise from local, municipal, or state
authorities in order to construct and operate a wireline network in a specific area, and then build
lines to homes in that area. A consumer cannot purchase video programming distribution
services from a wireline distributor operating outside its franchise area because the distributor
does not have the facilities to reach the consumer’s home. Thus, although the set of video
programming distributors able to offer service to individual consumers’ residences is generally
the same within each local community, the set can differ from one local community to another.
According to the Complaint, each local community whose residents face the same
competitive choices in video programming distribution comprises a geographic market and
section of the country under Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 18. The geographic
markets relevant to this action are the numerous local markets throughout the United States
where either Charter, TWC, or BHN is the incumbent cable operator – an area encompassing 48
million U.S. television households located across 41 states. However, because OVDs typically
offer services nationwide, the Complaint alleges that anticompetitive effects of the proposed
merger likely extend to the entire United States.
The incumbent cable companies are often the largest video distribution provider in their
respective local territories; the Defendants’ market shares, for example, exceed 50 percent in
many local markets in which they operate. The DBS providers, DirecTV and DISH Network,
account for an average of about one third of video programming subscribers combined in any
given local market. The telcos, including AT&T and Verizon, have market shares as high as 40
percent in the communities they have entered, but they are only available in limited areas and
account for about 10 percent of video programming customers nationwide. Overbuilders such as
Google Fiber can also have moderately high shares in particular local markets, but their services
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 7 of 27
8
are only available in a small number of areas and they account for fewer than two percent of
nationwide video programming distribution subscribers.
Although OVDs have acquired a significant number of customers over the last several
years, most of these customers also purchase traditional MVPD subscriptions. As a result,
OVDs currently have a small share of video programming distribution market revenues likely
around 5%.
D. Emerging Competition from OVDs in the Relevant Market
1. OVD Business Models and Participants
OVDs have developed a number of different business models for delivering content to
consumers. Several OVDs, including Netflix, Amazon Prime Instant Video, and Hulu Plus, offer
“subscription video on demand” (“SVOD”) services where consumers typically obtain access to
a
wide library of movies, past-season television shows, and original content for a subscription
fee.
3
In addition, some individual cable programmers, such as CBS and HBO, have begun
offering their content directly to consumers on an SVOD basis. For example, HBO’s service,
branded HBO NOW, provides subscribers who pay a monthly fee with access to the same HBO
content over the Internet that they would receive through a subscription to HBO as part of an
MVPD package.
In contrast to these SVOD providers, a few OVDs have recently begun offering MVPD-
like bundles of live, scheduled content to consumers over the Internet. In early 2015, DISH
launched Sling TV, a monthly subscription service that provides customers access to many of the
same cable networks that are available through traditional MVPDs. Sony has launched a similar
service called PlayStation Vue. Unlike SVODs, these “virtual” MVPDs (“vMVPDs”) provide
3
Hulu also offers current-season content from various television networks on an ad-supported
basis for no subscription fee.
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 8 of 27
9
customers the ability to watch live sports and news programming, as well as other scheduled
entertainment programming, at the same time it is available on traditional MVPDs.
2. The Effects of OVD Development on Traditional MVPDs
As OVDs have developed new business models and obtained a wider array of attractive
video content, they have started to become closer substitutes for traditional MVPD services.
Although many consumers treat OVD services as a complement to traditional MVPD service
for example, purchasing services from an SVOD like Netflix to access past season content and
Netflix’s original content but subscribing to an MVPD for live and current-season content –
some are already using OVDs as substitutes for at least a portion of their video consumption.
These consumers buy smaller content packages from traditional MVPDs, decline to take certain
premium channels, or purchase fewer VOD offerings, and instead substitute content from OVDs,
a practice known as “cord-shaving.” In addition, a small, but growing number of MVPD
customers are “cutting the cable cord” completely, using one or more OVDs as a replacement for
their MVPD service. Finally, some younger consumers are emerging as “cord nevers” who do
not seek out an MVPD subscription in the first place.
Absent interference from the established MVPDs, OVDs are likely to continue to grow,
and to become stronger competitors to MVPDs. Moreover, to the extent that OVDs continue to
develop services that more closely resemble those offered by traditional MVPDs, such as the live
programming offered by vMVPDs or the current season content offered by certain SVODs,
traditional MVPDs will likely face greater substitution to OVD services. To this end, the
Defendants’ internal documents show that they have typically been comparatively less concerned
about competition from certain SVOD providers, like Netflix, that do not offer live or current-
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 9 of 27
10
season programming, and more concerned by the threat posed by vMVPDs like Sling TV and
SVODs like HBO NOW that offer current season content.
3. Traditional MVPDs’ Responses to the Growth of OVDs
The Defendants and many other MVPDs recognize the threat that the growth of OVDs
pose to their video distribution businesses. Numerous internal documents reflect the Defendants’
assessment that OVDs are growing quickly and pose a competitive threat to traditional forms of
video programming distribution. MVPDs have responded to this growth in various ways. To
keep their customers from migrating some or all of their viewing to OVDs, many MVPDs,
including the Defendants, have introduced new and less expensive packages with smaller
numbers of channels, increased the amount of content available on an on-demand basis, and
made content available to subscribers on devices other than traditional cable set-top boxes. At
the same time, however, some MVPDs have sought to restrain nascent OVD competition directly
by exercising their leverage over video programmers to restrict video programmers’ ability to
license content to OVDs. As alleged in the Complaint, and explained in more detail below,
TWC has been an industry leader in seeking such restrictions, and the formation of New Charter
will create an entity with an increased ability and incentive to do so.
E. The Anticompetitive Effects of the Proposed Merger
Although Defendants do not compete to provide video distribution services to consumers
in the same local geographic markets, the Clayton Act is also concerned with mergers that
threaten to reduce the number or quality of choices available to consumers by increasing the
merging parties’ incentive or ability to engage in conduct that would foreclose competition.
4
For
4
See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 317 (1962) (noting that the Clayton Act
intended to make illegal “not only [] mergers between actual competitors, but also [] vertical and
conglomerate mergers whose effect may tend to lessen competition in any line of commerce in
any section of the country.”); FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.S. 568, 577 (1967) (“All
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 10 of 27
11
example, a merger may create, or substantially enhance, the ability or incentive of the merged
firm to protect its market power by denying or raising the price of an input to the firm’s rivals.
As alleged in the Complaint, New Charter will be significantly larger than each of the
Defendants individually, and thus will have a greater incentive and ability to use its bargaining
power with video programmers to protect its market power in the local markets for video
programming distribution. Specifically, following the merger, New Charter will be the one of
the largest MVPDs in the country, with over 17 million subscribers in 41 states, and will
therefore be a critical distribution channel for video programmers. The Complaint alleges that
this greater scale will give New Charter more leverage to demand that programmers agree to
limit their distribution to OVDs, enabling the merged firm to increase barriers to entry for OVDs
or otherwise make OVDs less competitive.
The Complaint also alleges that New Charter will have increased incentive to engage in
such behavior because it will stand to lose substantially more profits than Charter, TWC, and
BHN individually if OVDs take business from traditional MVPDs, and it will internalize more of
the benefits of harming OVDs. The Defendants’ specific means for foreclosing OVDs – ADM
clauses and other restrictive contracting provisions – are discussed in more detail below.
1. TWC Is the Industry Leader in Imposing ADMs and Other
Restrictive Programming Clauses that Limit Video Programmers’
Rights to License to OVDs
Video programmers sign lengthy licensing agreements with distributors that establish the
terms on which the distributors will carry the programmers’ networks. Sometimes, these
licensing agreements include restrictions on the other distributors to whom the programmer may
license content, or on other ways the programmer may make the content available to consumers.
mergers are within the reach of § 7, and all must be tested by the same standard, whether they are
classified as horizontal, vertical, conglomerate.”).
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 11 of 27
12
One type of restriction is often referred to in the industry as an “alternative distribution means”
(“ADM”) clause. ADM clauses take many forms, and in some cases can have significant
consequences for programmers’ ability to license to OVDs. For example, some ADMs prohibit a
video programmer from licensing content to OVDs for an extended period of time after the
content is first aired on traditional MVPDs – permanently blocking OVDs from being able to
offer current-season content from those programmers. Other ADMs prohibit the programmer
from licensing content to OVDs unless the OVDs meet a number of strict (and sometimes
elaborate) criteria that can be difficult to satisfy.
5
TWC has been the most aggressive MVPD at seeking and obtaining restrictive ADM
clauses in recent years. The Department’s review of hundreds of programming contracts and
ordinary course business documents revealed that TWC has obtained numerous ADMs that limit
distribution to paid OVDs. Other distributors, by contrast, have rarely, if ever, sought or
obtained such clauses, or have only obtained ADMs that are much less restrictive. TWC’s
success in seeking and obtaining ADMs is likely attributable in part to its bargaining leverage
over video programmers; although such programmers might disfavor such restrictions because
they require the programmer to forsake opportunities to earn revenues from OVDs, they are
more likely to agree to a large MVPD such as TWC’s demand to include them because they do
not want to lose access to TWC’s millions of cable subscribers.
The Department’s investigation further suggested that TWC may be the most aggressive
at obtaining such clauses because, other than Comcast, TWC has more to lose from the
expansion of OVDs than any other traditional MVPD. Although Comcast also has substantial
5
For instance, an ADM in one MVPD’s contract with a video programmer prohibited the
programmer from licensing to any OVD unless that OVD offered a package that included thirty-
five channels, including at least two channels each from three out of a list of six large video
programmers.
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 12 of 27
13
video profits at risk, it is prohibited from entering into or enforcing any provisions that restrict
distribution to OVDs under the terms of a consent decree entered in United States v. Comcast
Corp.
6
By contrast, distributors with fewer subscribers than TWC have less to lose from the
expansion of OVDs, and, in some cases, may actually support OVD expansion because they
make little or no profit margin on their video distribution businesses and would prefer to improve
the attractiveness of their broadband Internet access services. Meanwhile, the two DBS
providers, DISH and DirecTV, have historically been comparable to TWC in size, but because of
their different distribution technology and their customer demographics, may perceive a lower
threat from OVDs. In fact, DISH is offering an OVD service of its own – Sling TV – and
DirecTV recently announced plans to offer a similar OVD service.
2. The Proposed Transaction Increases New Charter’s Ability and
Incentive to Obtain ADMs and Other Restrictive Programming
Clauses
The number and scope of the ADMs that TWC obtained prior to the merger suggests that
TWC believes that these ADM clauses are worth whatever consideration it must provide video
programmers in return. After the merger, New Charter, with over 17 million video subscribers in
41 states, will have even more leverage than TWC to demand that programmers agree to ADMs.
Given the importance of New Charter as a distribution channel, programmers will be less likely
to risk losing access to New Charter’s considerable subscriber base – which is almost 60 percent
larger than TWC alone and will be more likely to accept to New Charter’s demands.
Moreover, since New Charter will have far more profits at risk from increased OVD competition
than Charter, TWC, or BHN standing alone, it will be willing to provide greater consideration to
programmers to obtain such clauses. As a result, New Charter can be expected to seek and
6
See Final Judgment, United States et al. v. Comcast et al., Civil Action No. 1:11cv-00106,
2011-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶77,585, 2011 WL 5402137 (D.D.C. Sept. 1, 2011), available at
https://www.justice.gov/atr/case-document/file/492196/download.
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 13 of 27
14
obtain ADMs with more programmers than TWC has to date, and the ADMs are likely to be
more restrictive than TWC’s current ADM provisions. As alleged in the Complaint, such ADMs
could negatively affect OVDs’ business models and undermine their ability to provide robust
video offerings that compete with the offerings of traditional MVPDs. The weakening of OVD
competition will result in lower-quality services, fewer consumer choices, and higher prices.
4. Entry Is Unlikely to Reverse the Anticompetitive Effects of the
Proposed Merger
Successful entry into the traditional video programming distribution business is difficult
and requires an enormous upfront investment to create a distribution infrastructure. As alleged
in the Complaint, additional entry into wireline or DBS distribution is not likely to be significant
for the next several years. Telcos have been willing to incur some of the enormous costs to
modify their existing telephone infrastructure to distribute video, and will continue to do so, but
only in certain areas. Other new providers, such as Google Fiber, are also expanding services,
but the time and expense required to build to each new area makes expansion slow. Therefore,
traditional MVPDs’ market shares are likely to be fairly stable over the next several years.
OVDs represent the most likely prospect for successful and significant competitive entry
into the existing video programming distribution market. However, in addition to the other
barriers they face, OVDs must obtain access to a sufficient amount of content to become viable
distribution businesses, and the proposed merger will likely increase that barrier to entry even
further.
III. EXPLANATION OF THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
The proposed Final Judgment ensures that New Charter will not impede competition by
using programming contracts to prevent the flow of content to OVDs. The proposed Final
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 14 of 27
15
Judgment thereby protects consumers by eliminating the likely anticompetitive effects of the
proposed merger alleged in the Complaint.
A. The Proposed Final Judgment Prohibits Defendants from Limiting
Distribution to OVDs through Restrictive Licensing Practices
As discussed above, certain types of contract provisions, such as ADMs, can have the
purpose and effect of limiting distribution to OVDs. However, not all provisions that limit
distribution are anticompetitive. Reflecting this reality, Sections IV.A and IV.B of the proposed
Final Judgment set forth broad prohibitions on restrictive contracting practices, while Section
IV.C delineates a narrowly tailored set of exceptions. Taken together, these provisions ensure
that New Charter cannot use restrictive contract terms to harm the development of OVDs, but
preserve programmers’ incentives to produce quality programming and New Charter’s ability to
compete with other distributors to obtain marquee content.
Section IV.A of the proposed Final Judgment prohibits New Charter from entering into or
enforcing agreements that forbid, limit, or create incentives to limit the provision of video
programming to OVDs. This language prevents New Charter from enforcing the ADM
provisions in current TWC contracts, or from entering into new provisions.
Section IV.B provides additional detail as to the types of terms that could create
“incentives to limit” distribution to OVDs. The Department’s investigation revealed that TWC
has obtained ADM provisions for the purpose of attempting to limit distribution to OVDs.
However, once those agreements are prohibited, New Charter could substitute ADMs with more
subtle types of contract provisions that do not directly limit distribution to OVDs, but make it
financially unattractive for video programmers to license content to OVDs. For instance, absent
relief, New Charter could enter into an agreement that permits a video programmer to license
content to an OVD, but specifies that so licensing will entitle New Charter to a massive license
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 15 of 27
16
fee discount. To prevent evasion of the ban on ADMs, Section IV.B.1 clarifies that such
“penalty” provisions that create incentives to limit distribution to OVDs are not permitted.
Alternatively, New Charter could enter into certain kinds of “most favored nation”
(“MFN”) provisions that are designed to create incentives to limit distribution to OVDs.
Although MFN provisions are ubiquitous in the industry – for example, many MVPDs use MFN
provisions entitling the MVPD to the lowest license fee that the programmer offers to any other
MVPD the Department’s investigation revealed that some MVPDs were utilizing certain
provisions that, while referred to as “MFNs,” actually require much more than equal treatment.
Specifically, some provisions, commonly referred to as “unconditional MFNs” or “cherry-
picking MFNs,” require that a programmer provide an MVPD the most favorable term the
programmer has offered to any other distributor, even if that other distributor agreed to
additional payment or other conditions in exchange for receiving that term.
7
As a result of an
unconditional MFN, the programmer may be reluctant to license the additional content to the
other distributor in the first place.
Although unconditional MFNs are uncommon today, and the Defendants have only a few
such provisions in their current contracts, the Department was concerned that New Charter could
replace ADMs with unconditional MFNs in an effort to circumvent the proposed Final Judgment.
For example, New Charter might obtain an unconditional MFN from a programmer that would
entitle New Charter to receive at no additional cost any content a programmer makes available to
7
For example, a programmer may enter into an agreement with Distributor A that provides
Distributor A with extra content (for instance, additional video-on-demand rights) in exchange
for an extra payment. If the programmer has an unconditional MFN with Distributor B, the
programmer may then be required to provide the additional video-on-demand rights to
Distributor B without Distributor B having to make the extra payment. By contrast, a more
typical and less problematic – MFN would entitle Distributor B to the additional content only if
Distributor B agreed to pay the same additional fee paid by Distributor A.
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 16 of 27
17
an OVD, regardless of payments or other conditions with which the OVD must comply. In such
case, by providing programming to an OVD, the programmer might face significant economic
disadvantages in the form of losing the opportunity to monetize the content through distribution
by New Charter. As a result, unconditional MFNs could create significant disincentives for
programmers to license content to OVDs. For these reasons, Section IV.B.2 of the proposed
Final Judgment prohibits New Charter from entering into or enforcing unconditional MFNs
against programmers for distributing their content to OVDs.
8
Section IV.C of the proposed Final Judgment establishes three narrow exceptions to the
broad prohibitions in Sections IV.A and IV.B. First, New Charter may prohibit the programmer
from making content available on the Internet for free for 30 days after its initial airing, if New
Charter has paid a fee for the video programming. The Department’s investigation revealed that
such limitations on free distribution are ubiquitous in the industry, and the Department has
discovered no evidence that such provisions are harmful to competition.
Second, New Charter may enter into an agreement in which the programmer provides
content exclusively to New Charter, and to no other MVPD or OVD. Although uncommon, a
few programmers wish to make some of their content available to only one distributor. This
relationship then incentivizes the distributor to vigorously market the content, and thus can be
procompetitive in some circumstances. The proposed Final Judgment ensures that New Charter
can continue to compete with other distributors to obtain these kinds of exclusives. As long as
the exclusivity applies to all other video programming distributors, and does not narrowly
8
Specifically, Section IV.B.2.i provides that New Charter may not require a programmer to
provide New Charter the same terms offered to an OVD unless New Charter also accepts any
conditions that are integrally related, logically linked, or directly tied to those terms. The
language chosen for this provision mirrors language that is common in conditional MFN
provisions throughout the industry. Also consistent with other conditional MFNs in the industry,
Section IV.B.2.ii states that Charter need not comply with related terms and conditions if it is
unable to do so for technological or regulatory reasons.
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 17 of 27
18
prohibit distribution only to OVDs, the Department has no basis to believe such provisions will
always or usually be harmful.
9
Third, New Charter may condition carriage of programming on its cable system on terms
which require it to receive as favorable material terms as other MVPDs or OVDs, except to the
extent such terms would be inconsistent with the purpose of the proposed Final Judgment. That
is, New Charter may enter into the kinds of ordinary conditional MFNs that are ubiquitous in the
industry, such as a provision which entitles New Charter to the lowest license fee paid by any
other distributor. This provision explicitly does not override Section IV.B.2’s ban on the
application of unconditional MFNs to OVD distribution. Importantly, New Charter may not use
MFNs as a back door to obtain provisions which are otherwise “inconsistent with the purpose of
Sections A and B.” For instance, even if another distributor obtains a provision which “create[s]
incentives to limit” a programmer’s provision of programming to an OVD, New Charter cannot
use an MFN to add that other distributor’s provision to New Charter’s own contract.
2. The Proposed Final Judgment Prohibits Defendants from Discriminating
Against, Retaliating Against, or Punishing Video Programmers
Section IV.D of the proposed Final Judgment prohibits Defendants from discriminating
against, retaliating against, or punishing any Video Programmer for providing programming to
any OVD. This provision ensures that even though Defendants are no longer permitted to
contractually prohibit or deter video programmers from licensing content to OVDs, the
Defendants are not able to instead deter such licensing through threats or punishment. Section
IV.D also prohibits Defendants from discriminating against, retaliating against, or punishing any
video programmer for invoking any provisions of the proposed Final Judgment or any FCC rule
9
The Department retains the authority to challenge under Sections 1 or 2 of the Sherman Act any
exclusive agreement in the future that the evidence demonstrates unreasonably restrains trade or
creates or enhances monopoly power. See Proposed Final Judgment at § VII (No Limitation of
Government Rights).
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 18 of 27
19
or order, or for furnishing information to the Department concerning Defendants’ compliance
with the proposed Final Judgment.
Negotiations between video programmers and MVPDs are often contentious, high-stakes
affairs, and it is common for one or both sides to the negotiation to threaten to walk away, or
even to temporarily terminate the relationship (sometimes called a “blackout” or “going dark”) in
order to secure a better deal. The proposed Final Judgment is not concerned with such
negotiating tactics and therefore clarifies that “[p]ursuing a more advantageous deal with a Video
Programmer does not constitute discrimination, retaliation, or punishment.” Rather, Section
IV.D is designed to prevent situations where New Charter intentionally decides to forgo an
agreement with a programmer that would otherwise be economical for New Charter in order to
obtain the long-term benefits of deterring video programmers from licensing content to OVDs or
cooperating with the Department or the FCC.
3. Provision of Defendants’ FCC Interconnection Reports
Although the Department’s Complaint focuses on the likely competitive harm resulting
from New Charter’s imposition of ADMs and other contractual restrictions on video
programmers, the Department also investigated the potential for the proposed merger to increase
the price New Charter will charge Internet content companies, including OVDs, for access to its
broadband subscribers. OVDs rely on broadband connections provided by other companies to
reach their customers, and the Defendants are also major providers of Internet access service.
Therefore, the Department examined whether the merger could increase both the incentive and
ability of New Charter to use its control over the interconnection to New Charter’s broadband
Internet service provider network to try and disadvantage online video competitors.
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 19 of 27
20
The FCC’s order approving the merger imposes an obligation on New Charter to make
interconnection available on a non-discriminatory, settlement-free basis to any Internet content
provider, transit provider, or content delivery network (“CDN”) who meets certain basic criteria.
Although this policy only directly protects those sending large volumes of traffic, even smaller
sources who do not qualify for direct interconnection ought to find ample bandwidth available at
competitive prices because large transit and CDN providers will be guaranteed access, and could
resell that capacity. Thus, the Department expects that the FCC’s order will prevent any merger-
related harm to Internet content companies, including OVDs. In light of the FCC’s remedy, the
Department did not target interconnection in its Complaint and elected not to pursue duplicative
relief with respect to interconnection in the proposed Final Judgment. However, in order to
assist the Department in monitoring future developments with regard to interconnection and in
taking whatever action might be appropriate to prevent anticompetitive conduct, Section IV.E
requires New Charter to provide the Department with copies of the regular reports that New
Charter furnishes to the FCC pursuant to the FCC’s order.
D. Term of the Proposed Final Judgment
Section VIII of the proposed Final Judgment provides that the Final Judgment will expire
seven years from the date of entry. The Department believes this time period is long enough to
ensure that New Charter cannot harm OVD competitors at a crucial point in their development
while accounting for the rapidly evolving nature of the video distribution market. After five
years, Section VIII permits Charter to request that the Department reevaluate whether the Final
Judgment remains necessary to protect competition. If at such time the Department concludes
that the market has evolved such that the protections of the decree are no longer necessary, it will
recommend to the Court that the Final Judgment be terminated.
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 20 of 27
21
IV. REMEDIES AVAILABLE TO POTENTIAL PRIVATE LITIGANTS
Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 15, provides that any person who has been
injured as a result of conduct prohibited by the antitrust laws may bring suit in federal court to
recover three times the damages the person has suffered, as well as costs and reasonable
attorneys’ fees. Entry of the proposed Final Judgment will neither impair nor assist the bringing
of any private antitrust damage action. Under the provisions of Section 5(a) of the Clayton Act,
15 U.S.C. § 16(a), the proposed Final Judgment has no prima facie effect in any subsequent
private lawsuit that may be brought against Defendants.
V. PROCEDURES AVAILABLE FOR MODIFICATION
OF THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
The United States and Defendants have stipulated that the proposed Final Judgment may
be entered by the Court after compliance with the provisions of the APPA, provided that the
United States has not withdrawn its consent. The APPA conditions entry upon the Court’s
determination that the proposed Final Judgment is in the public interest.
The APPA provides a period of at least 60 days preceding the effective date of the
proposed Final Judgment within which any person may submit to the United States written
comments regarding the proposed Final Judgment. Any person who wishes to comment should
do so within 60 days of the date of publication of this Competitive Impact Statement in the
Federal Register, or the last date of publication in a newspaper of the summary of this
Competitive Impact Statement, whichever is later. All comments received during this period
will be considered by the United States, which remains free to withdraw its consent to the
proposed Final Judgment at any time prior to the Court’s entry of judgment. The comments and
the response of the United States will be filed with the Court. In addition, comments will be
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 21 of 27
22
posted on the U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division’s internet website and, under certain
circumstances, published in the Federal Register. Written comments should be submitted to:
Scott A. Scheele
Chief, Telecommunications and Media Enforcement Section
Antitrust Division
United States Department of Justice
450 Fifth Street, N.W., Suite 7000
Washington, DC 20530
The proposed Final Judgment provides that the Court retains jurisdiction over this action,
and the parties may apply to the Court for any order necessary or appropriate for the
modification, interpretation, or enforcement of the Final Judgment.
VI. ALTERNATIVES TO THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
The United States considered, as an alternative to the proposed Final Judgment, seeking
preliminary and permanent injunctions against Defendants’ transactions and proceeding to a full
trial on the merits. The United States is satisfied, however, that the relief in the proposed Final
Judgment will preserve competition for the provision of video programming distribution services
in the United States. Thus, the proposed Final Judgment would protect competition as
effectively as would any remedy available through litigation, but avoids the time, expense, and
uncertainty of a full trial on the merits.
VII. STANDARD OF REVIEW UNDER THE APPA
FOR THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT
The Clayton Act, as amended by the APPA, requires that proposed consent judgments in
antitrust cases brought by the United States be subject to a sixty-day comment period, after
which the court shall determine whether entry of the proposed Final Judgment “is in the public
interest.” 15 U.S.C. § 16(e)(1). In making that determination, the court, in accordance with the
statute as amended in 2004, is required to consider:
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 22 of 27
23
(A) the competitive impact of such judgment, including termination of alleged
violations, provisions for enforcement and modification, duration of relief sought,
anticipated effects of alternative remedies actually considered, whether its terms
are ambiguous, and any other competitive considerations bearing upon the
adequacy of such judgment that the court deems necessary to a determination of
whether the consent judgment is in the public interest; and
(B) the impact of entry of such judgment upon competition in the relevant
market or markets, upon the public generally and individuals alleging specific
injury from the violations set forth in the complaint including consideration of the
public benefit, if any, to be derived from a determination of the issues at trial.
15 U.S.C. § 16(e)(1)(A) & (B). In considering these statutory factors, the Court’s inquiry is
necessarily a limited one as the government is entitled to “broad discretion to settle with the
defendant within the reaches of the public interest.” United States v. Microsoft Corp., 56 F.3d
1448, 1461 (D.C. Cir. 1995); see generally United States v. SBC Commc’ns, Inc., 489 F. Supp.
2d 1 (D.D.C. 2007) (assessing public interest standard under the Tunney Act); United States v,
U.S. Airways Group, Inc., 38 F. Supp. 3d 69, 75 (D.D.C. 2014) (explaining that the “court’s
inquiry is limited” in Tunney Act settlements); United States v. InBev N.V./S.A., No. 08-1965
(JR), 2009-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 76,736, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *3, (D.D.C. Aug. 11,
2009) (noting that the court’s review of a consent judgment is limited and only inquires “into
whether the government's determination that the proposed remedies will cure the antitrust
violations alleged in the complaint was reasonable, and whether the mechanism to enforce the
final judgment are clear and manageable.”).
10
As the United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit has held,
under the APPA a court considers, among other things, the relationship between the remedy
secured and the specific allegations set forth in the government’s complaint, whether the decree
10
The 2004 amendments substituted “shall” for “may” in directing relevant factors for courts to
consider and amended the list of factors to focus on competitive considerations and to address
potentially ambiguous judgment terms. Compare 15 U.S.C. § 16(e) (2004), with 15 U.S.C. §
16(e)(1) (2006); see also SBC Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 11 (concluding that the 2004
amendments “effected minimal changes” to Tunney Act review).
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 23 of 27
24
is sufficiently clear, whether enforcement mechanisms are sufficient, and whether the decree
may positively harm third parties. See Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1458-62. With respect to the
adequacy of the relief secured by the decree, a court may not “engage in an unrestricted
evaluation of what relief would best serve the public.” United States v. BNS, Inc., 858 F.2d 456,
462 (9th Cir. 1988) (quoting United States v. Bechtel Corp., 648 F.2d 660, 666 (9th Cir. 1981));
see also Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1460-62; United States v. Alcoa, Inc., 152 F. Supp. 2d 37, 40
(D.D.C. 2001); InBev, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *3. Courts have held that:
[t]he balancing of competing social and political interests affected by a proposed antitrust
consent decree must be left, in the first instance, to the discretion of the Attorney General.
The court’s role in protecting the public interest is one of insuring that the government
has not breached its duty to the public in consenting to the decree. The court is required
to determine not whether a particular decree is the one that will best serve society, but
whether the settlement iswithin the reaches of the public interest.” More elaborate
requirements might undermine the effectiveness of antitrust enforcement by consent
decree.
Bechtel, 648 F.2d at 666 (emphasis added) (citations omitted).
11
In determining whether a
proposed settlement is in the public interest, a district court “must accord deference to the
government’s predictions about the efficacy of its remedies, and may not require that the
remedies perfectly match the alleged violations.” SBC Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 17; see
also U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 75 (noting that a court should not reject the proposed
remedies because it believes others are preferable); Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 (noting the need
for courts to be “deferential to the government’s predictions as to the effect of the proposed
remedies”); United States v. Archer-Daniels-Midland Co., 272 F. Supp. 2d 1, 6 (D.D.C. 2003)
11
Cf. BNS, 858 F.2d at 464 (holding that the court’s “ultimate authority under the [APPA] is
limited to approving or disapproving the consent decree”); United States v. Gillette Co., 406 F.
Supp. 713, 716 (D. Mass. 1975) (noting that, in this way, the court is constrained to “look at the
overall picture not hypercritically, nor with a microscope, but with an artist’s reducing glass”).
See generally Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 (discussing whether “the remedies [obtained in the
decree are] so inconsonant with the allegations charged as to fall outside of the ‘reaches of the
public interest’”).
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 24 of 27
25
(noting that the court should grant due respect to the United States’ prediction as to the effect of
proposed remedies, its perception of the market structure, and its views of the nature of the case).
Courts have greater flexibility in approving proposed consent decrees than in crafting
their own decrees following a finding of liability in a litigated matter. “[A] proposed decree
must be approved even if it falls short of the remedy the court would impose on its own, as long
as it falls within the range of acceptability or is ‘within the reaches of public interest.’” United
States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 552 F. Supp. 131, 151 (D.D.C. 1982) (citations omitted) (quoting
United States v. Gillette Co., 406 F. Supp. 713, 716 (D. Mass. 1975)), aff’d sub nom. Maryland
v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983); see also U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 76 (noting that
room must be made for the government to grant concessions in the negotiation process for
settlements (citing Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461); United States v. Alcan Aluminum Ltd., 605 F.
Supp. 619, 622 (W.D. Ky. 1985) (approving the consent decree even though the court would
have imposed a greater remedy). To meet this standard, the United States “need only provide a
factual basis for concluding that the settlements are reasonably adequate remedies for the alleged
harms.” SBC Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 17.
Moreover, the court’s role under the APPA is limited to reviewing the remedy in
relationship to the violations that the United States has alleged in its Complaint, and does not
authorize the court to “construct [its] own hypothetical case and then evaluate the decree against
that case.” Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1459; see also U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 75 (noting that
the court must simply determine whether there is a factual foundation for the government’s
decisions such that its conclusions regarding the proposed settlements are reasonable); InBev,
2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *20 (“the ‘public interest’ is not to be measured by comparing
the violations alleged in the complaint against those the court believes could have, or even
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 25 of 27
26
should have, been alleged”). Because the “court’s authority to review the decree depends
entirely on the government’s exercising its prosecutorial discretion by bringing a case in the first
place,” it follows that “the court is only authorized to review the decree itself,” and not to
“effectively redraft the complaint” to inquire into other matters that the United States did not
pursue. Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1459-60. As this Court confirmed in SBC Communications, courts
“cannot look beyond the complaint in making the public interest determination unless the
complaint is drafted so narrowly as to make a mockery of judicial power.SBC Commc’ns, 489
F. Supp. 2d at 15.
In its 2004 amendments, Congress made clear its intent to preserve the practical benefits
of utilizing consent decrees in antitrust enforcement, adding the unambiguous instruction that
“[n]othing in this section shall be construed to require the court to conduct an evidentiary hearing
or to require the court to permit anyone to intervene.” 15 U.S.C. § 16(e)(2); see also U.S.
Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 76 (indicating that a court is not required to hold an evidentiary
hearing or to permit intervenors as part of its review under the Tunney Act). The language wrote
into the statute what Congress intended when it enacted the Tunney Act in 1974, as Senator
Tunney explained: “[t]he court is nowhere compelled to go to trial or to engage in extended
proceedings which might have the effect of vitiating the benefits of prompt and less costly
settlement through the consent decree process.” 119 Cong. Rec. 24,598 (1973) (statement of Sen.
Tunney). Rather, the procedure for the public interest determination is left to the discretion of
the court, with the recognition that the court’s “scope of review remains sharply proscribed by
precedent and the nature of Tunney Act proceedings.” SBC Commc’ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 11.
12
12
See United States v. Enova Corp., 107 F. Supp. 2d 10, 17 (D.D.C. 2000) (noting that the
“Tunney Act expressly allows the court to make its public interest determination on the basis of
the competitive impact statement and response to comments alone”); United States v. Mid-Am.
Dairymen, Inc., No. 73-CV-681-W-1, 1977-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 61,508, at 71,980, *22 (W.D.
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 26 of 27
27
A court can make its public interest determination based on the competitive impact statement and
response to public comments alone. U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 76.
VIII. DETERMINATIVE DOCUMENTS
Appendix B to the FCC’s Memorandum Opinion and Order, In re Applications of
Charter Communications, Inc., Time Warner Cable Inc., and Advance/Newhouse Partnership for
Consent to the Transfer of Control of Licenses and Authorizations, FCC MB Docket No. 15-149
(adopted May 5, 2016; released May 10, 2016), was the only determinative document or material
within the meaning of the APPA considered by the Department in formulating the proposed
Final Judgment. This document is available on the FCC’s website at
https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs public/attachmatch/FCC-16-59A1.pdf, and will also be made
available on the Antitrust Division’s website at https://www.justice.gov/atr/case/us-v-charter-
communications-inc-et-al.
Dated: May 10, 2016
Respectfully submitted,
/s/
Robert A. Lepore
Telecommunications & Media
Enforcement Section
Antitrust Division
U.S. Department of Justice
450 Fifth Street, N.W., Suite 7000
Washington, DC 20530
Telephone: (202) 532-4928
Facsimile: (202) 514-6381
Mo. 1977) (“Absent a showing of corrupt failure of the government to discharge its duty, the
Court, in making its public interest finding, should . . . carefully consider the explanations of the
government in the competitive impact statement and its responses to comments in order to
determine whether those explanations are reasonable under the circumstances.”); S. Rep. No. 93-
298, at 6 (1973) (“Where the public interest can be meaningfully evaluated simply on the basis
of briefs and oral arguments, that is the approach that should be utilized.”).
Case 1:16-cv-00759-RCL Document 7 Filed 05/10/16 Page 27 of 27